• Subscriber Services
  • For Authors
  • Publications
  • Archaeology
  • Art & Architecture
  • Bilingual dictionaries
  • Classical studies
  • Encyclopedias
  • English Dictionaries and Thesauri
  • Language reference
  • Linguistics
  • Media studies
  • Medicine and health
  • Names studies
  • Performing arts
  • Science and technology
  • Social sciences
  • Society and culture
  • Overview Pages
  • Subject Reference
  • English Dictionaries
  • Bilingual Dictionaries

Recently viewed (0)

  • Save Search
  • Share This Facebook LinkedIn Twitter

Related Content

Related overviews.

Eurocentrism

See all related overviews in Oxford Reference »

More Like This

Show all results sharing this subject:

media hegemony

Quick reference.

The theory, derived from Gramscian Marxism, that an elite controls the mass media, and that the media promote the dominant ideology. See also consciousness industry; hegemony; manufacture of consent. The audience is not necessarily compliant ( see dominant reading; negotiated reading; oppositional reading). ‘Corporate media hegemony’ refers to the global dominance and influence of powerful commercial mass media organizations and a transnational elite. ‘Western media hegemony’ refers to a perception that global news media are dominated by Eurocentric values and perspectives ( see also media imperialism). Critics argue that ritualistic use of the concept reflects reification and determinism and underestimates the contestation highlighted by Gramsci.

From:   media hegemony   in  A Dictionary of Media and Communication »

Subjects: Media studies

Related content in Oxford Reference

Reference entries.

View all related items in Oxford Reference »

Search for: 'media hegemony' in Oxford Reference »

  • Oxford University Press

PRINTED FROM OXFORD REFERENCE (www.oxfordreference.com). (c) Copyright Oxford University Press, 2023. All Rights Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single entry from a reference work in OR for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice ).

date: 27 June 2024

  • Cookie Policy
  • Privacy Policy
  • Legal Notice
  • Accessibility
  • [109.248.223.228]
  • 109.248.223.228

Character limit 500 /500

Mass Media and Hegemonic Knowledge : Gramsci and the Representation of the ‘Other’

  • First Online: 18 July 2018

Cite this chapter

research on media hegemony

  • Salomi Boukala 2  

923 Accesses

This chapter seeks to develop a theoretical framework to enhance Gramsci’s contribution to CDA and media studies. In particular, I first refer to the elliptic relation between CDA and hegemony. Then, I discuss the concept of intellectuals, and the distinction between traditional and organic intellectuals; I reintroduce the concept of hegemony and present those of superstructureand passive revolution. The next section includes discussions on the functions of the mass media, news values and media representations of the ‘Other’. It also refers to the links between CDA and media studies regarding representation of the ‘Other’, and emphasizes the representation of the Muslim ‘Other’ in order to justify why Gramsci’s work is essential to the study of media representations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
  • Durable hardcover edition

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

At this point I should mention that Michel Foucault ( 1980 ) also emphasized the concept of power and claims that power does not have directly to do with violence but is similar to a form of control over peoples’ consciences and actions. According to Foucault, what makes power hold good, what makes it accepted, is simply the fact that it does not only weigh on ‘us’ as a force that says no. It traverses and produces things, induces pleasure, forms knowledge, produces discourse. It needs to be considered as a productive network which runs through the whole social body, much more than a negative instance whose function is repression ( 1980 , pp. 117–120, 141–143). Foucault also noted that the ‘mechanizations’, which can produce discourse and knowledge of what is accepted and what is not, are the state, scientists and intellectuals (ibid.). Hence, the first reading of the two concepts shows that Foucault’s power is close to Gramsci’s hegemony . However, I decided to focus on Gramsci’s hegemony because, from my viewpoint, it is more accomplished in relation to Foucault’s concept of power and Bourdieu’s symbolic power ( 1991 ) insofar as it includes class and resistance dynamics (counter-hegemony), and it seems to be a holistic approach to the modern capitalist state and its institutions.

For example, see: Triandafyllidou et al. ( 2009 ), Wodak ( 2008a , b ), Madianou ( 2005 ), Hall ( 1995 , 1997b , 1982 ), Richardson ( 2007 ), KhosraviNik ( 2015a , b ), Lacey ( 1998 ), Morley and Robins ( 1995 ), Hannerz ( 2004 ), Halliday ( 1999 ), Chomsky ( 2001 , 2002 ), and McQuail ( 2000 ).

A presentation of all the studies on critical discourse analysis of media is not possible in the limited space of this book. However, I would like to mention that this study was inspired by works such as: Richardson ( 2004 , 2007 , 2009 ), KhosraviNik ( 2015a , b ), Macgilchrist ( 2011 ), Sandikcioglu ( 2000 ), Meadows ( 2005 ), Tekin ( 2010 ), Le ( 2002 , 2010 ), Oberhuber et al. ( 2005 ), Krzyzanowski ( 2009 ), and Triandafyllidou et al. ( 2009 ).

Van Dijk had earlier examined a number of media-research studies on migrants and their representation in the British press and deduced that minority groups were not represented as being part of British society, but rather as dangerous ‘outsiders’ ( 1987 , pp. 40–45). Moreover, he assumed that the media play a central role in the reproduction of racism through the symbolic polarization between positive ‘Us’ and negative ‘Them’ ( 1993 , pp. 243–252).

Chomsky ( 2002 ), Fairclough ( 2006 ), and Nacos ( 2005 ).

The term ‘war on terror’ had been used by American President Reagan (1983). President Reagan labeled the states of Eastern Europe, the Middle East and Latin America as a ‘cancer’, a ‘source of terrorism’, ‘rogue states’ and introduced the term ‘war on terror’ as part of an effort to pass legislation that was designed to freeze the assets of terrorist groups and marshal government forces against them. President G. W. Bush repeated the term in his addresses to the American people after 9/11 (Chomsky 1999 , 2001 ).

See KhosraviNik ( 2015b ), Triandafyllidou et al. ( 2009 ), Richardson ( 2004 ), Schudson ( 2003 ), Fairclogh ( 1995a ), and Fowler ( 1991 ).

Here I should mention that there are other theories, such as the encoding/decoding model of Stuart Hall ( 2005 ), that focus on audiences’ defenses against media power. In any case I cannot ignore these theories, but I do need to highlight the fact that in this study I intend to approach mass media discourse as a form of institutional and hegemonic discourse.

Abbas, T. (2001). Media Capital and the Representation of South Asian Muslims in the British Press: An Ideological Analysis. Journal of Muslim Minority Affairs, 21 (2), 245–257.

Article   Google Scholar  

Arendt, H. (1970). On Violence . Orlando: Harcourt Publishing Company.

Google Scholar  

Barker, C. (1999). The Construction and Representation of Race and Nation. In C. Barker (Ed.), Television, Globalization and Cultural Identities . Buckingham: Open University Press.

Baker, P., Wodak, R., et al. (2008). A Useful Methodological Synergy? Combining Critical Discourse Analysis and Corpus Linguistics to Examine Discourses of Refugees and Asylum Seekers in the UK Press. Discourse & Society, 19 (3), 273–305.

Born, G. (2004). Uncertain Vision . London: Secker & Warburg.

Bourdieu, P. (1991). Language and Symbolic Power . London: Polity Press.

Buci-Glucksmann, C. (1980). Gramsci and the State . London: Lawrence and Wishart.

Buci-Glucksmann, C. (1982). Hegemony and Consent: A Political Strategy. In A. Showstack-Sasoon (Ed.), Approaches to Gramsci . London: Writers and Readers Publishing Cooperative Society.

Chomsky, N. (1999). Acts of Aggression, Policing “Rogue” States . New York: Seven Stories Press.

Chomsky, N. (2001). 9–11. New York: Seven Stories Press.

Chomsky, N. (2002). Media Control: The Spectacular Achievements of Propaganda . New York: Seven Stories Press.

Cramer, P. (2008). Controversy as a Media Event Category. In B. Johnstone & C. Eisenhart (Eds.), Rhetoric In Detail (pp. 279–305). Amsterdam: John Benjamins Publishing Company.

Curtin, M. (1995). Redeeming the Wasteland: Television Documentary and Cold War Politics. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press.

Eldridge, J. (1995). Glasgow University Media Group Reader, Vol. I . London: Routledge.

Fairclough, N. (1992). Discourse and Social Change . London: Polity.

Fairclough, N. (1995a). Media Discourse . London: Arnold.

Fairclough, N. (1995b). Critical Discourse Analysis . London: Longman.

Fairclough, N. (2006). Language and Globalisation . London: Routledge.

Femia, J. (1981). Gramsci’s Political Thought: Hegemony, Consciousness and the Revolutionary Press . Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Filippini, M. (2017). Using Gramsci: A New Approach . London: Pluto Press.

Foucault, M. (1980). Power/Knowledge: Selected Interviews and Other Writings 1972–1977 . London: Harvester Wheatsheaf.

Fowler, R. (1991). Language in the News: Discourse and Ideology in the Press . London: Routledge.

Gramsci, A. (1971). Selections from the Prison Notebooks . London: Lawrence and Wishart.

Hall, S. (1982). The Rediscovery of Ideology: Return of the Repressed in Media Studies. In O. Boyd-Barrett & C. Newbold (Eds.), Approaches to Media . London: Arnold.

Hall, S. (1995). The Whites of Their Eyes: Racist Ideologies and the Media. In G. Dines & J. M. Humes (Eds.), Gender, Race and Class in Media. London: Sage.

Hall, S. (1997a). The Work of Representation. In S. Hall (Ed.), Representation: Cultural Representations and Signifying Practices . London: Sage.

Hall, S. (1997b). The Spectacle of the ‘Other’. In S. Hall (Ed.), Representation: Cultural Representations and Signifying Practices . London: Sage.

Hall, S. (2005). Encoding-Decoding. In S. Hall et al. (Eds.), Culture, Media, Language (pp. 128–138). London: Routledge.

Halliday, F. (1999). Manipulation and Limits: Media Coverage of the Gulf War 1990–91. In T. Allen & J. Seaton (Eds.), The Media of Conflict: War Reporting and Representations of Ethnic Violence . London: Zed Books.

Hannerz, U. (2004). Foreign News, Exploring the World of Foreign Correspondents . Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Huntington, S. (1999). The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order . New York: Simon and Schuster.

Ives, P. (2004). Language and Hegemony in Gramsci . London: Pluto Press.

Karim, K. (2003). Islamic Peril: Media and Global Violence . London: Black Rose.

KhosraviNik, M. (2015a). Macro and Micro Legitimation in Discourse on Iran’s Nuclear Programme: The Case of Iranian National Newspaper Kayhan. Discourse & Society, 26 (1), 52–73.

KhosraviNik, M. (2015b). Discourse, Identity & Legitimacy: Self and Other in Representations of Iran’s Nuclear Programme . Amsterdam: John Benjamins Publishing Company.

Book   Google Scholar  

Krzyzanowski, M. (2009). Europe in Crisis? Journalism Studies, 10 (1), 18–35.

Lacey, N. (1998). Image and Representation: Key Concepts in Media Studies . Basingstoke: Macmillan.

Laclau, E., & Mouffe, C. (1985). Hegemony and Socialist Strategy . London: Verso.

Le, E. (2002). The Concept of Europe in Le Monde’s Editorials: Tensions in the Construction of a European Identity. Journal of Language and Politics, 1 (2): 277–322.

Le, E. (2010). Editorials and the Power of Media . Amsterdam: John Benjamins Publishing Company.

Macgilchrist, F. (2011). Journalism and the Political: Discursive Tensions in News Coverage of Russia . Amsterdam: John Benjamins Publishing Company.

Madianou, M. (2005). Mediating the Nation . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

McNair, B. (1988). Images of the Enemy . London: Routledge.

McQuail, D. (2000). Mass Communication Theory . London: Sage.

Meadows, B. (2005). Distancing and Showing Solidarity via Metaphor and Metonymy in Political Discourse. A Critical Study of American Statements on Iraq During the Years 2004–2005. CADAAD, 1 (2), 1–17.

Morley, D., & Robins, K. (1995). Spaces of Identity . London: Routledge.

Nacos, B. (2005). Mass-Mediated Terrorism: The Central Role of the Media in Terrorism and Counterterrorism . New York: Rowman and Littlefield.

Oberhuber, F., Bärenreuter, C., Krzyzanowski, M., Schönbauer, H., & Wodak, R. (2005). Debating the European Constitution: On Representations of Europe/the EU in the Press. Journal of Language and Politics, 4 (2), 227–271.

Preston, P., & Metykova, M. (2009). Media, Political Communication and the European Public Sphere. In A. Triandafyllidou, R. Wodak, & M. Krzyzanowski (Eds.), The European Public Sphere and the Media: Europe in Crisis . London: Palgrave Macmillan.

Richardson, J. (2004). (Mis)Representing Islam: The Racism and Rhetoric of British Broadsheet Newspapers . Amsterdam: John Benjamins.

Richardson, J. (2007). Analysing Newspapers: An Approach from Critical Discourse Analysis . London: Palgrave Macmillan.

Richardson, J. (2009). ‘Get Shot of the Lot of Them’: Election Reporting of Muslims in British Newspapers. Patterns of Prejudice , 43(3–4): 355–377.

Richardson, J., & Wodak, R. (2009). Recontextualising Fascist Ideologies of the Past: Right-Wing Discourse on Employment and Nativism in Austria and the United Kingdom. Critical Discourse Studies, 6 (4), 251–267.

Said, E. (1991). Imaginative Geography and its Representations. In E. Said (Ed.), Orientalism . Harmondsworth: Penguin.

Sandikcioglu, E. (2000). More Metaphorical Warfare in the Gulf: Orientalist Frames in News Coverage. In A. Barcelona (Ed.), Metaphor and Metonymy at the Crossroads: A Cognitive Prospective . New York: Mouton de Gruyter.

Sardar, Z. (1999). Orientalism . London: Sage.

Schudson, M. (2003). The Sociology of News . London: W. W. Norton & Company.

Showstack-Sassoon, A. (1980). Gramsci’s Politics . London: Croom Helm.

Showstack-Sassoon, A. (1982). Hegemony, War of Position and Political Intervention. In A. Showstack-Sassoon (Ed.), Approaches to Gramsci . London: Writers and Readers Publishing Cooperative Society.

Sreberny, A. (2002). The Global and the Local in International Communication. In J. Curran & M. Gurevitch (Eds.), Mass Media and Society (3rd ed.). London: Arnold.

Tekin, B. (2010). Representation and Othering in Discourse: The Construction of Turkey in the EU Context . Amsterdam: John Benjamins.

Thomas, P. (2009). The Gramscian Moment: Philosophy, Hegemony and Marxism . Leiden: Brill.

Todorov, T. (2008). La Peur des Barbares: Au-delà du choc des civilizations . Paris: Robert Laffont.

Triandafyllidou, A., Wodak, R., & Krzyzanowski, M. (Eds.). (2009). The European Public Sphere and the Media: Europe in Crisis . London: Palgrave Macmillan.

Van Dijk, T. (1987). Communicating Racism: Ethnic Prejudice in Thought and Talk . London: Sage.

Van Dijk, T. (1988). News as Discourse . London: Lawrence Elbraum Associates.

Van Dijk, T. (1993). Elite Discourse and Racism . London: Sage.

Wodak, R. (2004). National and Transnational Identities: European and Other Identities Constructed in Interviews with EU Officials. In R. Hermann & T. Risse (Eds.), Transnational Identities: Becoming European in the EU . Oxford: Rowman and Littlefield.

Wodak, R. (2008a). ‘Us’ and ‘Them’: Inclusion and Exclusion—Discrimination Via Discourse. In G. Delanty, R. Wodak, & P. Jones (Eds.), Identity, Belonging and Migration . Liverpool: Liverpool University Press.

Wodak, R. (2008b). The Contribution of Critical Linguistics to the Analysis of Discriminatory Prejudices and Stereotypes in the Language of Politics. In R. Wodak & V. Koller (Eds.), Handbook of Communication in the Public Sphere . Berlin: Walter de Gruyter.

Wodak, R. (2009a). Language and Politics. In J. Culpeper, F. Katamba, P. Kerswill, R. Wodak, & T. McEnery (Eds.), English Language: Description, Variation and Context (pp. 576–593). London: Palgrave Macmillan.

Chapter   Google Scholar  

Wodak, R. (2009b). Prejudice, Racism and Discourse. In A. Pelinka, K. Bischof, & K. Stagner (Eds.), Aspects of Prejudice a Handbook . New York: Cambria Press.

Wodak, R. (2011). The Discourse of Politics in Action: Politics as Usual . London: Palgrave.

Wodak, R. (2015). The Politics of Fear: What Right-Wing Populist Discourses Mean . London: Sage.

Zassoursky, Y. (1991). Changing Images of the Soviet Union and the United States. In E. Dannis, G. Gerbrner, & Y. Zassoursky (Eds.), Beyond the Cold War: Soviet and American Media Images . London: Sage.

Download references

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Panteion University of Social and Political Sciences, Athens, Greece

Salomi Boukala

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Salomi Boukala .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Boukala, S. (2019). Mass Media and Hegemonic Knowledge : Gramsci and the Representation of the ‘Other’. In: European Identity and the Representation of Islam in the Mainstream Press. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-93314-6_3

Download citation

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-93314-6_3

Published : 18 July 2018

Publisher Name : Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

Print ISBN : 978-3-319-93313-9

Online ISBN : 978-3-319-93314-6

eBook Packages : Social Sciences Social Sciences (R0)

Share this chapter

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Publish with us

Policies and ethics

  • Find a journal
  • Track your research
  • Search Menu

Sign in through your institution

  • Advance articles
  • Author Guidelines
  • Submission Site
  • Open Access
  • Why Submit?
  • About Public Opinion Quarterly
  • About the American Association for Public Opinion Research
  • Editorial Board
  • Advertising and Corporate Services
  • Journals Career Network
  • Self-Archiving Policy
  • Dispatch Dates
  • Journals on Oxford Academic
  • Books on Oxford Academic

Issue Cover

  • < Previous

Media Hegemony: A Failure of Perspective

  • Article contents
  • Figures & tables
  • Supplementary Data

DAVID L. ALTHEIDE, Media Hegemony: A Failure of Perspective, Public Opinion Quarterly , Volume 48, Issue 2, SUMMER 1984, Pages 476–490, https://doi.org/10.1086/268844

  • Permissions Icon Permissions

Numerous studies of TV news have been published since Gans's (1972) call for more research on the mass media. A central issue underlying much of this research is control and dominance of the news process. This essay analyzes the logical and empirical adequacy of media hegemony as an explanation of ideological dominance. Analysis of recent research shows that some researchers have uncritically adapted the “dominant ideology thesis” of media hegemony to studies of TV news and have overlooked findings which challenge their claims about (1) the socialization and ideology of journalists, (2) whether news reports perpetuate the status quo, and (3) the nature and extent of international news coverage. Despite the shortcomings of the concept of media hegemony, efforts should continue to develop an empirically sound theoretical perspective for locating the news process in a broader societal context.

American Association for Public Opinion Research members

Personal account.

  • Sign in with email/username & password
  • Get email alerts
  • Save searches
  • Purchase content
  • Activate your purchase/trial code
  • Add your ORCID iD

Institutional access

Sign in with a library card.

  • Sign in with username/password
  • Recommend to your librarian
  • Institutional account management
  • Get help with access

Access to content on Oxford Academic is often provided through institutional subscriptions and purchases. If you are a member of an institution with an active account, you may be able to access content in one of the following ways:

IP based access

Typically, access is provided across an institutional network to a range of IP addresses. This authentication occurs automatically, and it is not possible to sign out of an IP authenticated account.

Choose this option to get remote access when outside your institution. Shibboleth/Open Athens technology is used to provide single sign-on between your institution’s website and Oxford Academic.

  • Click Sign in through your institution.
  • Select your institution from the list provided, which will take you to your institution's website to sign in.
  • When on the institution site, please use the credentials provided by your institution. Do not use an Oxford Academic personal account.
  • Following successful sign in, you will be returned to Oxford Academic.

If your institution is not listed or you cannot sign in to your institution’s website, please contact your librarian or administrator.

Enter your library card number to sign in. If you cannot sign in, please contact your librarian.

Society Members

Society member access to a journal is achieved in one of the following ways:

Sign in through society site

Many societies offer single sign-on between the society website and Oxford Academic. If you see ‘Sign in through society site’ in the sign in pane within a journal:

  • Click Sign in through society site.
  • When on the society site, please use the credentials provided by that society. Do not use an Oxford Academic personal account.

If you do not have a society account or have forgotten your username or password, please contact your society.

Sign in using a personal account

Some societies use Oxford Academic personal accounts to provide access to their members. See below.

A personal account can be used to get email alerts, save searches, purchase content, and activate subscriptions.

Some societies use Oxford Academic personal accounts to provide access to their members.

Viewing your signed in accounts

Click the account icon in the top right to:

  • View your signed in personal account and access account management features.
  • View the institutional accounts that are providing access.

Signed in but can't access content

Oxford Academic is home to a wide variety of products. The institutional subscription may not cover the content that you are trying to access. If you believe you should have access to that content, please contact your librarian.

For librarians and administrators, your personal account also provides access to institutional account management. Here you will find options to view and activate subscriptions, manage institutional settings and access options, access usage statistics, and more.

Short-term Access

To purchase short-term access, please sign in to your personal account above.

Don't already have a personal account? Register

Month: Total Views:
November 2016 2
January 2017 10
February 2017 21
March 2017 20
April 2017 34
May 2017 29
June 2017 9
July 2017 13
August 2017 23
September 2017 16
October 2017 71
November 2017 114
December 2017 52
January 2018 28
February 2018 43
March 2018 67
April 2018 43
May 2018 19
June 2018 6
July 2018 4
August 2018 4
September 2018 7
October 2018 16
November 2018 25
December 2018 12
January 2019 13
February 2019 12
March 2019 63
April 2019 28
May 2019 26
June 2019 10
July 2019 7
August 2019 13
September 2019 4
October 2019 24
November 2019 21
December 2019 16
January 2020 17
February 2020 12
March 2020 17
April 2020 14
May 2020 14
June 2020 7
July 2020 2
August 2020 2
September 2020 8
October 2020 10
November 2020 26
December 2020 18
January 2021 14
February 2021 9
March 2021 20
April 2021 33
May 2021 38
June 2021 13
July 2021 5
August 2021 11
September 2021 9
October 2021 16
November 2021 18
December 2021 28
January 2022 19
February 2022 11
March 2022 22
April 2022 29
May 2022 34
June 2022 8
July 2022 8
August 2022 1
September 2022 7
October 2022 16
November 2022 22
December 2022 23
January 2023 13
February 2023 19
March 2023 21
April 2023 21
May 2023 23
June 2023 8
July 2023 4
August 2023 10
September 2023 7
October 2023 17
November 2023 22
December 2023 15
January 2024 11
February 2024 13
March 2024 28
April 2024 28
May 2024 22
June 2024 2

Email alerts

Citing articles via.

  • Recommend to your Library

Affiliations

  • Online ISSN 1537-5331
  • Copyright © 2024 American Association for Public Opinion Research
  • About Oxford Academic
  • Publish journals with us
  • University press partners
  • What we publish
  • New features  
  • Open access
  • Rights and permissions
  • Accessibility
  • Advertising
  • Media enquiries
  • Oxford University Press
  • Oxford Languages
  • University of Oxford

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University's objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide

  • Copyright © 2024 Oxford University Press
  • Cookie settings
  • Cookie policy
  • Privacy policy
  • Legal notice

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

This PDF is available to Subscribers Only

For full access to this pdf, sign in to an existing account, or purchase an annual subscription.

Logo

Brill | Nijhoff

Brill | Wageningen Academic

Brill Germany / Austria

Böhlau

Brill | Fink

Brill | mentis

Brill | Schöningh

Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht

V&R unipress

Open Access

Open Access for Authors

Transformative Agreements

Open Access and Research Funding

Open Access for Librarians

Open Access for Academic Societies

Discover Brill’s Open Access Content

Organization

Stay updated

Corporate Social Responsiblity

Investor Relations

Policies, rights & permissions

Review a Brill Book

 
 
 

Author Portal

How to publish with Brill: Files & Guides

Fonts, Scripts and Unicode

Publication Ethics & COPE Compliance

Data Sharing Policy

Brill MyBook

Ordering from Brill

Author Newsletter

Piracy Reporting Form

Sales Managers and Sales Contacts

Ordering From Brill

Titles No Longer Published by Brill

Catalogs, Flyers and Price Lists

E-Book Collections Title Lists and MARC Records

How to Manage your Online Holdings

LibLynx Access Management

Discovery Services

KBART Files

MARC Records

Online User and Order Help

Rights and Permissions

Latest Key Figures

Latest Financial Press Releases and Reports

Annual General Meeting of Shareholders

Share Information

Specialty Products

Press and Reviews

 
   
   
   
   

Hegemony, Ideology, Media

Purchase instant access (PDF download and unlimited online access):

Share link with colleague or librarian

Media, ideology and hegemony.

Cover Media, Ideology and Hegemony

Table of Contents

All Time Past Year Past 30 Days
Abstract Views 18321 1469 48
Full Text Views 425 82 2
PDF Views & Downloads 226 119 3

Reference Works

Primary source collections

COVID-19 Collection

How to publish with Brill

Open Access Content

Contact & Info

Sales contacts

Publishing contacts

Stay Updated

Newsletters

Social Media Overview

Terms and Conditions  

Privacy Statement  

Cookie Settings  

Accessibility

Legal Notice

Terms and Conditions   |   Privacy Statement   |  Cookie Settings   |   Accessibility   |  Legal Notice   |  Copyright © 2016-2024

Copyright © 2016-2024

  • [109.248.223.228]
  • 109.248.223.228

Character limit 500 /500

Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.

To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to  upgrade your browser .

Enter the email address you signed up with and we'll email you a reset link.

  • We're Hiring!
  • Help Center

paper cover thumbnail

Role of Media in Hegemony and Subcultures

Profile image of Gabriel Caballero

This paper discusses Dick Hebdige’s ideas on subcultures, hegemony, and how they can be applied to recent cases in which mass media have played a significant role in totally different cultures and contexts. The first case study looks at how the belief system of the British Royal Family has been normalised in British (and global) society, emphasising the values of law, tradition, and proper behaviour. The second case study reflects on China’s political decision to create a “monolingual” and “monocultural” nation and where ethnic communities like the Manchu try to resist such cultural influence, keeping their traditions alive. In today’s globalised cultures, mass media is a powerful tool because of its ability to reach out to the majority of society, even beyond traditional borders. There is almost no way to avoid its reach with messages that promote certain values. These values represent ideologies from a certain perspective, thus whoever controls the media controls the identity formation of society.

Related Papers

Randa Aboubakr

research on media hegemony

Researching Subcultures, Myths and Memory

J. Patrick Williams

This chapter discusses the ways in which mythical stories of the origins of subcultures and the authenticity of subcultural identities have influenced subculture research since the 1970s. It states that neither the origin stories nor the authentic identities may be real, but that people nonetheless believe in them and base their actions on these beliefs. Based on these findings, the chapter proposes to approach subcultural myths in a pragmatic way, as constructed and negotiated stories that hold great importance for subcultural actors and scholars alike.

David Harris

A critique of the development of Cultural Studies in Britain, especially the work of the CCCS and OU Popular Culture Group

Shawn Pitre

Timothy Bei

Samuel Rodrigues

gautam mitra

Apercu of Gramsci

Ben T Pettis

This thesis examines Internet memes, a unique medium that has the capability to easily and seamlessly transfer ideologies between groups. It argues that these media can potentially enable subcultures to challenge, and possibly overthrow, hegemonic power structures that maintain the dominance of a mainstream culture. I trace the meme from its creation by Matt Furie in 2005 to its appearance in the 2016 US Presidential Election and examine how its meaning has changed throughout its history. I define the difference between a meme instance and the meme as a whole, and conclude that the meaning of the overall meme is formed by the sum of its numerous meme instances. This structure is unique to the medium of Internet memes and is what enables subcultures to use them to easily transfer ideologies in order to challenge the hegemony of dominant cultures.

Loading Preview

Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.

RELATED PAPERS

freddy thom

Dr. Awais H. Gillani

Christian Wicke

Lotus White

Christopher Little

David Schmid

Chrysa Mantziou

Marilo Cabrera

Angelique Suzette Pineda

Responding to youth

International Journal of Middle East Studies

John McManus

Jaspal Naveel Singh

The International Encyclopedia of Communication Theory and Philosophy

Studies in Eastern European Cinema

Dijana Jelača

Sociology Compass

Neville Borg

Sam Chapman

Ifigeneia Vamvakidou , Anastasia Christodoulou , Lazaros Papoutzis , Argyris Kyridis

Cheryl Mahmoud

Joseph MacKay

Andrew Phillips

Tori Wilton

Revista Alicantina de Estudios Ingleses

Lucia Esposito

Meaghan Morris

David A Koppers

Pricsilla WaGitonga

Nick Bentley

laras aphrodit

Rosana Pinotti

Elizabeth A Stinson

Zeynep Nagihan Kahveci

David Burke

RELATED TOPICS

  •   We're Hiring!
  •   Help Center
  • Find new research papers in:
  • Health Sciences
  • Earth Sciences
  • Cognitive Science
  • Mathematics
  • Computer Science
  • Academia ©2024
  • Tools and Resources
  • Customer Services
  • Conflict Studies
  • Development
  • Environment
  • Foreign Policy
  • Human Rights
  • International Law
  • Organization
  • International Relations Theory
  • Political Communication
  • Political Economy
  • Political Geography
  • Political Sociology
  • Politics and Sexuality and Gender
  • Qualitative Political Methodology
  • Quantitative Political Methodology
  • Security Studies
  • Share This Facebook LinkedIn Twitter

Article contents

Hegemony and the global political economy.

  • Richard Saull Richard Saull School of Politics and International Relations, Queen Mary University of London
  • https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190846626.013.208
  • Published in print: 01 March 2010
  • Published online: 22 December 2017

Hegemony emerged as an analytical term to conceptualize different historical periods out of the combined post-1945 historical context of two key events: the dissolution of an international political order founded upon European colonial empires, and the establishment and evolution of a postwar liberal international economy under U.S. leadership. Within the subdiscipline of International Political Economy (IPE), the genesis of the concept of “hegemony” or “leadership” has two sources: the idea of hegemonic order or dominance within the world economy as articulated in Immanuel Wallerstein’s World-Systems Theory in the early 1970s, and the publication of Charles Kindleberger’s analysis of the Great Depression that initiated a debate involving neorealist and liberal-oriented scholars around what subsequently become known as “hegemonic stability theory.” John Ikenberry also articulated a nuanced understanding of hegemony from a liberal-institutionalist perspective with regard to the post-1945 international order. There exists a substantial amount of literature on the theory and history of hegemony within IPE, and much of this discussion has been fueled by ongoing developments in the world economy. Critics of hegemony situate and embed state power and behavior within the socioeconomic structure of capitalism, and also focus on class agency as central to the establishment and evolution of hegemonic orders. To varying degrees these scholars have drawn on the theory of hegemony developed by Antonio Gramsci.

  • International Political Economy
  • hegemonic order
  • Immanuel Wallerstein
  • World-Systems Theory
  • Charles Kindleberger
  • hegemonic stability theory
  • John Ikenberry
  • liberal institutionalism

Introduction

The concept of hegemony refers to international leadership by one political subject, be it the state or a “historical bloc” of particular social groupings, whereby the reproduction of dominance involves the enrollment of other, weaker, less powerful parties (states/classes) constituted by varying degrees of consensus, persuasion and, consequently, political legitimacy. Force is not completely absent within hegemonic arrangements but it tends to be the exception rather than the rule with regard to the upholding of the hegemonic order. It contrasts with empire and imperialism whereby patterns of dominance and hierarchy are founded upon a systemic dependence on the deployment of direct and political coercion in the maintenance of imperial arrangements and where political subjectivity is deprived by the dominant power. Further, hegemony has a more ambivalent connection to questions of territoriality and borders than empire, which is primarily concerned with the determination of frontiers by a metropolitan power.

Hegemony is a political term that has a long history, found in Machiavelli’s Prince ( 1977 :49–50) referring to the centaur, a creature that is part human and part beast combining force and persuasion, and later in debates among Russian revolutionaries about the leadership of the worker’s revolution. It emerged as an analytical term to conceptualize different historical periods out of the combined post- 1945 historical context of (1) the dissolution of an international political order founded upon European colonial empires; and (2) the establishment and evolution of a postwar liberal international economy under American leadership. With regard to the former, the reproduction of the postcolonial international order no longer required – as it had done in the past – the deployment of force to uphold political arrangements; hence the possibility of hegemonic rather than imperial leadership was made more likely. However, notwithstanding this transformation, the legacy of empire is such that hegemony has tended to refer to political arrangements among the advanced capitalist states, while force, contestation and resistance have been much more common currencies in “North–South relations” since 1945 .

Regarding the latter, although the geopolitical context of the Soviet “threat” played an important role in facilitating the development of the unprecedented forms of political and economic cooperation among the leading capitalist states after the war, the specificities of the internationalization of American territorial power through multilateral institutions were particularly attuned to hegemony. Hegemony, then, refers to leadership and to the consensual character of those leadership arrangements. Although a hegemonic order does not have to be associated with the development and upholding of a liberal international political economy, the two historical cases – Britain during the late nineteenth century and the United States after 1945 – most cited by scholars as exemplars of hegemonic order have been liberal, which suggests that hegemony is particularly associated with liberal social and political orders rather than any other.

The genesis of the concept of “hegemony” or “leadership” in the subdiscipline of International Political Economy (IPE) has two sources. First, the idea of hegemonic order or dominance within the world economy was articulated within the World-Systems Theory (WST) approach by Immanuel Wallerstein ( 1974 ) in the early 1970s through his articulation of a general theory of hegemonic transition to explain long-cycles of capitalist development, which also addressed the apparent demise of US hegemony in particular. Secondly, the publication of Charles Kindleberger’s ( 1973 ) analysis of the Great Depression initiated a debate – that has ebbed and flowed with the fluctuating performance of the US economy since – involving neorealist and liberal-oriented scholars around what subsequently become labeled as “hegemonic stability theory” (HST). This debate, which has tended to eclipse the WST approach to hegemony, has centered around the question of the degree to which a smooth-functioning open and liberal international economy requires political leadership from a “hegemonic state.”

Whereas traditional views on hegemony tend to have a state-centric ontology, critical views embed the agency of states within the socioeconomic structure of capitalism. Consequently, hegemony is not understood, primarily, as an international political order or geopolitical arrangement between discrete territorial entities but rather the upholding of a particular set of socioeconomic relations – mediated by states and international institutions – but concerning asymmetrical patterns of class relations within (transnational) civil society that, to varying degrees, are considered as extending beyond a specific territorial locale. What is intended in the rest of this essay is to discuss these two broad viewpoints on hegemony, addressing the main elements of each theory and their respective historical coverage.

Traditional Views

Hegemonic stability theory.

HST is an attempt to (1) explain the historical specificity of the postwar liberal international economic order through a focus on the benign consequences of an uneven distribution of material power in the international system; and (2) offer a more general theoretical framework to account for international order in contrast to the more orthodox realist concept of the balance of power. The immediate international economic context was signal in the emergence of such claims, as it was the collapse of the postwar Bretton Woods international economic order based upon US leadership that appeared to have triggered a bout of international economic instability and disorder. After it emerged in the writings of Kindleberger ( 1973 ; 1981 ) and Gilpin ( 1972 ; 1981 ; 1987 ) in particular, HST quickly became a widely accepted explanation for the evolution of the world economy after 1945 and the particular role of the United States within it, because it appeared to reflect the empirical reality of an international economy characterized by gradual trade liberalization combined with the material dominance of the United States.

Following Susan Strange ( 1987 :554–5; see also Wyatt-Walter 1996 ), it is possible to recognize two variants of HST. The first, neorealist, version suggests that a hegemon will ensure international economic order and stability when it uses its power to enforce others to obey the rules of the economic game. The assumption here is that in the absence of such rules enforced by the hegemon, international economic relations quickly degenerate into mercantilist beggar-thy-neighbor policies as states “free ride” on the open and liberal provisions of the world economy in response to the “prisoner’s dilemma” of not knowing whether rules will be enforced or acquiesced to. This triggers retaliations by other states, culminating in systemic breakdown and the establishment of imperial-protectionist trading blocs (Gilpin 1987 :88; Krasner 1976 ; 1982 ; Kindleberger 1981 :247).

The second, neoliberal, strand developed a little later, as a critique and refinement of HST, within a historical context where the earlier expectations of post-hegemonic economic instability and disorder had not occurred. This strand of HST argues that while the material power and political dominance/leadership of a hegemon is an important factor facilitating (liberal) economic order, it is not sufficient to the realization of order and stability. Further, the absence of a hegemon may not, necessarily, result in instability and disorder. Such arguments make reference to the surprising level of stability in the world economy and the increasing scope and effectiveness of international regimes since the late 1970s – in the absence of a singular hegemonic economic power.

Comments here will be focused, initially, toward the former, before looking at the neoliberal variant of HST identified with the work of Robert Keohane in particular (Keohane and Nye 1977 ; Keohane 1980 ; 1984 ). The final part of this section will then go on to consider liberal-institutionalist readings of hegemony, which, while recognizing the centrality of the United States in postwar liberal international economic order, give much greater emphasis to the role played by institutional and nonmaterial factors (norms, ideas, assumptions, etc.) in constituting hegemony.

Adopting a neorealist frame of explaining international order via the distribution of material power across states, advocates of HST suggest that international economic order, and open, liberal ones in particular, are synchronized with the rise and fall of great powers (Gilpin 1981 :156–7). Indeed, as Isabelle Grunberg ( 1990 :434–7) has remarked, HST – in its neorealist form at least – has a distinct conception of world politics in time and space based on the assumption that world order derives from some form of hierarchical political arrangement that recurs, cyclically. This amounts to a geopolitical determinism in that, because of the underlying anarchical properties of the international system, its historical evolution amounts to a sequence of international hierarchies with one great power dominating the system succeeded by another, usually through war (Gilpin 1981 :144; 1987 :72). While Gilpin recognized the difficulties of applying this “historical tendency” in a world of nuclear weapons with regard to the question of American economic decline from the early 1970s, this general systemic tendency remains a key element within HST. This is not only a problem for the theoretical coherency of HST, but also, as will be demonstrated below, it undermines its ability to recognize the plural and evolving character of the international economy across historical time.

A fundamental realignment of material power in the international system is where hegemons and hegemonic orders emerge from. Although such changes have a long-term genesis in the economic development of particular states, historically they have been a consequence of major war between great powers (Gilpin 1981 :186–210). So, in the two empirical cases of hegemony identified by HST – the so-called Pax Britannica of the mid-late nineteenth century and the post- 1945 Pax Americana – it was the geopolitical conclusions of armed conflict that facilitated the development of hegemonic arrangements.

However, HST is specifically concerned with accounting for liberal forms of international economic order and not the generic characteristics of international economic relations per se. Consequently, hegemony does not, necessarily, arise from the uneven material structure of the international system, as such asymmetry has – as in the past – led to the establishment of empires and imperial economic orders (Gilpin 1987 :72). Therefore, what will determine the character of hierarchy is the domestic political-ideological character of the leading state. In short, states constituted by and committed to the practice of a liberal politics are likely to establish and uphold hegemonic arrangements; those that are not are likely to veer toward empire. This is obviously a key assumption with regard to debates about the economic rise of China and the international political consequences flowing from this.

The focus on accounting for a liberal international economy obviously “waters down” the explanatory significance of hard-material territorial power in HST, and therefore opens up a theoretical ambivalence as to the causal determination and agency accounting for hegemony. Thus, while the hegemon is materially dominant in both its economic and military capabilities, it is only hegemonic to the degree that the order it seeks to establish and uphold promotes open, rule-guided, cooperative and liberal international economic exchange involving the cooperation of other states. In turn these secondary states perceive material benefits flowing from such arrangements, which obviously reduces the material advantages and coercive powers at the hegemon’s disposal. According to Gilpin ( 1981 :144), then, Britain and the United States “succeeded in this hegemonic role partially because they have imposed their will on lesser states and partially because other states have benefited from and accepted their leadership.” Such a position not only opens up the contingent domain of domestic politics and social-ideological conflict in the theorization of hegemony (which is not considered by HST), but also implies an assumption of benevolence on the part of the hegemon. Accordingly, the benefits flowing to the hegemon are less material (Kindleberger 1981 ) than in the form of status and prestige, which contradicts the realist-material logic at the heart of the theory.

What, then, makes the two empirical episodes of hegemonic order liberal and hegemonic? The key factor is the provision of collective or public goods, or what have been labeled international regimes that help sustain a liberal international (economic) order. Regimes can be defined as sets of principles, norms, rules, and decision-making procedures around which actor expectations converge on a given issue area proscribing illegitimate behavior to limit conflict and facilitate agreement (Gilpin 1987 :75). This is particularly emphasized by the neoliberal strand of HST (see Keohane and Nye 1977 ; Keohane 1980 ; 1984 ; Nye 1990 ; Snidal 1985 ; Gowa 1989 ). The provision of an open market for the exchange of goods and services free from political interventions and infringements is the most important collective good sustained by the hegemonic order as it allows market actors to compete with each other through the price mechanism rather than through proximity to political power. For Kindleberger ( 1981 :243), what defines the open market as a public good is that the consumption of it – open market access – by one or more actors does not reduce its availability to other producers. With Britain’s turn toward free trade after 1846 and the United States’s commitment to trade liberalization after 1945 there is some historical evidence to support the HST case that liberal and hegemonic orders necessitate the commitment by at least one leading state to open market exchange to overcome the prisoner’s dilemma (Guzzini 1998 :143).

The provision of public/collective goods extends beyond this to specific dimensions of the operations of the liberal international economy as exemplified by Britain during the late nineteenth century and the United States after 1945 . The key ones are (1) the management of the international financial system through the provision of an international currency for payment and a system for managing exchange rates; (2) the provision of capital through acting as a lender of last resort in moments of liquidity contraction; and (3) the promotion and stabilization of free trade through opening the country’s markets to other states, particularly in moments of crisis (Gilpin 1972 ; 1987 ; Kindleberger 1981 ; 1986 ; Lake 1993 :462).

The historical records of British and American hegemonies do, to a considerable degree, bear these out. Thus, throughout the latter decades of the nineteenth century until 1914 , British policy was committed to the provision of these collective goods: the promotion of free trade even if this wasn’t always reciprocated by its main trading partners; the City of London as the international clearing bank and provider of international liquidity; and a foreign exchange framework through the London-centered Gold Standard (Ruggie 1998 :71). With regard to the United States, it also established international regimes of collective goods after 1945 that formed the backbone of the postwar liberal economy: the Bretton Woods system of managed exchange rates supervised by the International Monetary Fund (IMF); the dollar as the principal unit of international economic exchange and the US export of dollars through aid, and military spending associated with the Cold War; and, finally, the promotion of trade liberalization through trade rounds under the auspices of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, and toleration of degrees of trade protectionism by its partners.

However, critics have questioned the degree to which these historical cases are best explained through HST. In particular, as Wyatt-Walter ( 1996 :126–9) notes, by occluding an analysis of the role played by the wider geopolitical context and security factors in the two historical episodes of hegemony, there are questions as to whether or not HST properly accounts for the character of leadership and the political dynamics driving the evolution of each hegemonic order. Thus, with regard to Britain, its leadership was strongly conditioned by imperial economic arrangements. In part because of this, its main trading partners were much less committed to a liberal ideological consensus in their domestic and international economic relations, which questions the degree of reciprocity qua regime involving other states under British hegemony. Consequently, there was no internationally agreed economic architecture based on a domestic consensus of other states (Mjøset 1990 :31). Instead, British economic advantage combined with the dividends it secured from its imperial preference system meant that it could tolerate nonreciprocity from many of its European trading partners. Further, Britain did not have the will or means to impose its vision of economic order on these states, which challenges the degree to which this historical episode is comparable with the post- 1945 episode of American hegemony (Latham 1997 :11–41).

Regarding the Pax Americana, HST appears to be vindicated in that US material power initially prevailed, with the 1944 Bretton Woods agreement reflecting an American vision of how the postwar international economic order should be organized, and also in securing concessions from Britain regarding the elimination of imperial preferences. However, this was to be short-lived. Within a couple of years a combination of a severe economic crisis in Western Europe – out of which it was feared communist parties in France and Italy might gain political advantage – combined with the escalation of US–Soviet geopolitical hostility with the development of the Cold War to reverse US plans (Saull 2007 :61–8). What came to drive US postwar economic planning after 1947 , then, was not the United States deploying its overwhelming power to establish its vision of how the postwar international economic order should be organized, but, rather, a realization that US national security interests required the United States to make a number of concessions to the other leading capitalist states (Pollard 1985 ; Wyatt-Walter 1996 :134). In sum, US and liberal economic objectives were subordinated to those of national security. While this does not mean that we can collapse postwar American hegemony, or the broader postwar liberal international economic regime, with the geopolitical context of the Cold War, it should give us pause for thought on the explanation of the substance and dynamics of postwar international economic order through the prism of HST.

A key aspect of hegemonic order according to HST is the provision of collective goods or what David Lake calls an “international economic infrastructure” ( 1993 :462). This requires an asymmetry of power in the international system, from which the material burden of providing such goods can be resourced and, politically, regimes established and rules enforced. However, because of its liberal character, the success – in terms of its international political legitimacy – of the hegemonic order serves to undermine the material basis of its long-term reproduction due to the more rapid economic growth – via “free riding” – of secondary states. Consequently, there is an assumption that hegemonic orders tend to be more beneficial – economically – to subordinate parties at the cost of the long-term economic health of the hegemon (Gilpin 1981 :44–5; 1987 :89; Stein 1984 ). Hence, the self-interested logic of a realist focus on the preservation of material power is challenged by the upholding and promotion of a liberal international economic order. The long-term outcome is a fiscal crisis of the dominant power as it can no longer maintain its external political and economic commitments, which is revealed in its relative decline and the unraveling of the material basis of the hegemonic order. For HST this can only be resolved with the emergence of a new hegemonic power to take on leadership responsibilities (Gilpin 1981 :155–7).

In such scenarios “centrifugal forces increasingly assert themselves” (Gilpin 1987 :76) and the hegemon becomes increasingly unable and unwilling to provide the collective goods and ensure the maintenance of economic regimes. While this dynamic of decline and the emergence of a new hegemon exhibits a propensity toward determinism, it does highlight a key contradiction within the dynamics of capitalist development – its tendencies toward deterritorialization – and the economic and political consequences of this on territorially bounded concentrations of material power.

It appears, then, that the dynamic of liberal capitalism unleashed by the hegemonic order supersedes the singular territorial power of the hegemon. This suggests that the rules of the economic regimes that “govern” the economic relations within the hegemonic order are relatively autonomous of the hegemon’s material power and political direction (Guzzini 1998 :147). In other words they are constructed and operate in such a way that they do not track the material power relations favoring the hegemon, which, further, suggests that either the hegemonic system is in some ways autonomous of the hegemon or that the hegemon acts in a selfless manner knowing full well that its material power and political autonomy are being circumscribed; yet its continuing, if declining leadership, remains legitimate. It is not clear, then, how the theory of hegemonic decline is compatible with that of hegemonic stability.

The historical record does indeed bear out the relative decline of hegemons evidenced by the experience of British global power in the years preceding World War I, and in the American case, the collapse of the economic order that it had established after World War II, in the early 1970s. Yet, while in the British case a new hegemon did emerge after two world wars, the cyclical logic of HST has not, yet, been realized with regard to the post-Pax Americana. The two episodes of hegemonic decline are, then, very distinct and, as O’Brien ( 2003 ) suggests, it is difficult to build a general historical trend and theoretical framework around such varied historical experiences and when, in the case of American decline, the consequences are historically inconclusive.

In the British case, decline was less a product of the uneven and paradoxical consequences of a liberal international economic order. Thus the market system did not – autonomously – undermine the material basis of the hegemonic order but, rather, emerged from the contradictions imminent within an only partially liberalized economic order (Panitch and Gindin 2003 ). The challenges to the existing order emerged, primarily, in the geopolitical realm. It was not, then, a case of the hegemon’s relative decline and it acting in an assertive, nationalistic, and protectionist fashion to try and forestall its decline. Instead, it was the emergence of geopolitical challenges to British power leading to war which provides a clue to both the deficiency of material hierarchy and liberalism in the international economic order of the late nineteenth century , and hence, what some scholars regard as its nonhegemonic character (McKeown 1983 ; Latham 1997 :11–41; Lacher 2006 :122–3).

In contrast, the “end” of the American hegemonic order occurred through the unilateral decisions of the hegemon (Gilpin 1987 ; Krasner 1976 ; 1982 ). The reasons for the unilateral abrogation by the United States of its obligations toward the Bretton Woods system in August 1971 were a consequence of (1) the material burden and economic drain of the Cold War, and the Vietnam War in particular; and (2) its relative competitive economic decline vis-à-vis the main Western European and Japanese economies. It is also important to note the significance of the geopolitical context of détente with the Soviet Union in informing US policy (Saull 2007 :132–8). With the collapse of the Bretton Woods arrangements, according to HST international economic relations became much more unstable, defined by a “predatory hegemony” (Krasner 1982 ; Gilpin 1987 :90, 345) reflected in unilateral actions outside of the frameworks of international regimes, notably during the Reagan administration.

Despite the abrogation of Bretton Woods and the relative decline of the material capacities of the US economy, the United States has remained geopolitically ascendant, especially since the end of the Cold War. Further, and challenging HST expectations, a new regime of globalized accumulation has emerged since the 1970s and the United States has been at the forefront of its promotion through the establishment of international institutions such as the World Trade Organization (WTO) and in shaping the ideological prescriptions of the Bretton Woods institutions. Stephen Gill ( 2003 ; see also Panitch and Gindin 2003 ) sees this transformation as reflecting a deliberate policy shift by the United States to address its economic vulnerabilities exposed by developments in the early 1970s. Paradoxically, then, this apparently post-hegemonic era saw – during the 1990s in particular – a revitalization of the American economy with the emergence of new technological and industrial sectors and a hegemonic dominance anchored in financial rather than industrial capital.

Susan Strange ’s work captures many of these developments through her recognition of what she regarded as continuing US advantage in the key aspects of “structural power” – security, credit, knowledge, and production – (Strange 1988 ) in the world economy even while the relationship between state power and markets had undergone a major reconfiguration since the 1980s (Strange 1996 ). For Strange, then, the HST debate about US hegemonic decline was too wedded to the British analogy (Strange 1987 :563, 565–71) and tended to overlook the empirical evidence of continuing US innovation, leadership, and hierarchy through the imposing of theoretical assumptions of inevitable decline/transition.

The essay will now turn to the work of Robert Keohane , whose critique and refinement of HST has developed a neoliberal variant of HST and, in doing so, has tried to address some of the criticisms mentioned above.

Economic Order and Regimes After Hegemony

Emerging in a similar international historical context to that of the other variant of HST, Keohane’s work has been concerned with explaining the continuing relevance and expansion of forms of international cooperation through regimes in the management of the international economy and the role of the United States within these arrangements (Keohane and Nye 1972 ; 1977 ; Keohane 1980 ; 1984 ). Consequently, Keohane’s work, most notably in his book-length study of the postwar international economic order, After Hegemony ( 1984 ), has formed a major contribution to the debate on HST and the articulation of what he calls a more subtle form of HST (Keohane 1984 :34–5) than that associated with the “more realist” work of Kindleberger, Gilpin, and Krasner.

The basis of Keohane’s ( 1984 :31) argument is that while a hegemon can facilitate the establishment and maintenance of international cooperation manifested in international economic regimes, “there is little reason to believe that hegemony is either a necessary or a sufficient condition for the emergence of cooperative relationships.” Indeed, as evidenced by post–Bretton Woods developments in the global economy, cooperation and regime development and effectiveness do not, contra Gilpin and Kindleberger, require a hegemon (Keohane 1984 :34–5). In many respects Keohane focuses on the ambivalence identified above in the explanatory power of the uneven distribution of material power and its necessary relationship with the liberal domestic political and ideological characteristics of the United States in particular. Therefore, the postwar international economic order is hegemonic and, more importantly, cooperative and regimes-based, because of the liberal domestic political character of the major states within it and the United States in particular.

Keohane also qualifies or reduces the theoretical ambition of HST as a general theoretical formula in IPE by stressing the differences between British economic leadership in the late nineteenth century compared to the United States after 1945 ( 1984 :37; see also Ruggie 1998 :121). Thus, for an order to be hegemonic whereby political relations between states are characterized by institutional cooperation and reciprocity (i.e., regimes), they need to extend beyond formal diplomatic arrangements anchored in power asymmetries, and instead equate to what Keohane terms “complex interdependence” (Keohane and Nye 1972 ; 1977 ) involving a range of actors – not just states – which rests on a drawing together of internal–external relations. These revisions to HST give it greater historical focus, if reducing its theoretical scope, and offer a route out of the ambivalent connection between material power, state interest, and liberal political economy.

In developing his critique, Keohane is concerned with accounting for post-hegemonic developments in the international monetary and trade regimes ( 1984 :206–10). And, in contrast to neorealist HST, he argues that multilateral institutions remained central to the operations of these economic relations, and further, they continued to be grounded in a liberal vision of political economy. Thus, in contrast to Gilpin’s claim of increasing unilateralism and system instability and breakdown, Keohane suggests cooperation and regime(s) formation without hegemony. Thus, in this revised account of the post-hegemonic order, a liberal regime-centered international economy continues to develop through “intensive interaction among a few players [which] helps to substitute for, or supplement, the actions of a hegemon” (Keohane 1984 :78–9).

What Keohane appears to be saying, then, is that post-hegemonic cooperation is possible because of the recognition by self-interested and rational egoists that such arrangements continue to benefit states ( 1984 :244–6). John Ruggie ( 1998 :64–5, 84) complements this line of reasoning by claiming that the decline of US power did not imply the collapse of the system because of the continuation of shared cross-national “social purpose” among leading states. So, as long as domestic social constituencies and prevailing ideational currents are supportive, the political consequences of material decline can be mitigated.

While Keohane offers a powerful critique of the neorealist strand of HST, the assumptions that guide his explanation of the “post-hegemonic” international economic order are questionable. Further, in a similar fashion to the neorealist strand of HST, his failure to sufficiently integrate geopolitical developments associated with the Cold War and security factors more generally also raises questions over the historical accuracy of his explanation of postwar hegemony (Wyatt-Walter 1996 :126–9). Indeed, as Guzzini recognizes ( 1998 :149), while the substance and relative material power of the United States has shifted, even declined, the United States has continued to remain as the dominant capitalist economy, and further, has been instrumental in reconfiguring the social, technological, and ideological character of the world capitalist economy since the early 1970s (see Calleo 1987 ; Strange 1987 ; 1988 ). It seems, then, that hierarchical relationships and the particular political and economic interests associated with the United States continue to condition the character of international economic order rather than, as Keohane suggests, consensual and largely harmonious relations emerging from a decentered structure and rationally motivated actors identifying shared objectives.

Relatedly, as his critics (Cox 1987 ; Gill 1995 ) suggest, Keohane ( 1984 ; 1989 ) tends to overlook the domestic shifts in the socioeconomic basis of US support for (neo)liberal institutional arrangements and how this has played itself out in the transfor-mation of the content and direction of these regimes. The continuing relevance of asymmetries in socioeconomic and political power is particularly relevant with respect to the expansion of the spatial coverage of regimes to much of the global South through the 1980s, where the US has been at the forefront in promoting neoliberal economic doctrines (Augelli and Murphy 1988 ). This may not matter to Keohane – who appears to regard liberal models of political economy as a positive sum – but it is something that Gill ( 1995 ; 2003 ; see also Robinson 2004 ) argues needs to be better substantiated through an assessment of the uneven consequences of neoliberal globalization and the way in which hierarchical political and social arrangements continue to condition the flow of economic benefits from the operations of the global economy.

Hegemony and Liberal Institutionalism

John Ikenberry ’s work has gone furthest in articulating a nuanced understanding of hegemony from a liberal-institutionalist perspective with regard to the post- 1945 international order (Ikenberry and Kupchan 1990 ; Ikenberry 1998 ; 2001a ; 2001b ; 2001c ; 2004 ). While agreeing with the basic claim of HST that the geopolitical and geo-economic transformations wrought by systemic war provide the most important foundations for the establishment of hegemonic international orders (Ikenberry 1998 ; 2001a :5), he has outlined an alternative understanding to the two strands of HST outlined above. In particular, he has sought to combine an examination of the peculiarities and uniqueness of postwar American hegemony grafted onto a general theory accounting for liberal hegemonic orders based on (1) the way in which international institutions bind a hegemon to other states, thus diffusing and legitimizing its (asymmetric) power; and (2) the way in which the internal social and political properties of liberal democracies facilitate and are constituted by a plurality of viewpoints, decentralized structures of power and decision making, and multiple channels of influence grounded in a transparent legal framework (Ikenberry 2001a :164–5).

Ikenberry ( 2004 ) distances himself further from HST in contesting the inevitability of hegemonic decline. Thus much of his work has been concerned with accounting for the continuation of American hegemony after the Cold War, when the postwar geopolitical context that helped sustain American leadership disappeared. This resulted in a much starker asymmetrical distribution of geopolitical power – American unipolarity – which was further enhanced during the 1990s when the US economy recaptured an element of dynamism, innovation, and growth and pioneered neoliberal globalization.

What marks out Ikenberry’s work – and this is where he parts company with Keohane ( 1980 ; 1984 ) and Ruggie ( 1998 ) in particular – is his claim that liberal hegemony, exemplified by the structures and institutions developed by the United States since 1945 , has a strong constitutional dimension. He defines a constitutional-based (international) order as an order “organized around agreed-upon legal and political institutions that operate to allocate rights and limit the exercise of power” and where the stakes in “political struggles are reduced by the creation of institutional processes of participation and decision making that specify rules, rights and limits on power holders” (Ikenberry 2001a :29). The key features of a constitutional order which can be applied to post- 1945 American hegemony are (1) shared agreement on basic principles and rules (the rules of the game); (2) rules and institutional arrangements that establish binding and authoritative limits on the exercise of power; and (3) rules and institutions that are embedded in the wider political system, that is, among other states/political elites which make them difficult to alter (Ikenberry and Kupchan 1990 ; Ikenberry 2001a :30–1). What this amounts to is an internationalization of the domestic political-ideological properties of the United States, suggesting that the open, orderly, predictable political arrangements that help curb executive and coercive power within the United States are transposed to the international sphere in the institutional arrangements established and developed by the United States (Ikenberry 2001a ; 2001b :203–4).

The upshot, then, is that for liberal democracies in general and the United States in particular the creation of “interlocking institutions” helps sustain an international order that “mutes the importance of power asymmetries within international relations,” providing a constitutional basis for international order and ending up “limiting the returns to power” (Ikenberry 2001a :6, 29). While hierarchical because of the continuing material dominance of the United States, Ikenberry suggests that both the hegemon and associated states abide by the rules of the institution/regime “because they accept them as desirable [and] they embrace them as their own” (Ikenberry 2001a :52). Further, Ikenberry argues that associated states, particularly in Western Europe, have, themselves, shaped and continue to mold institutional and substantive political and economic arrangements in their own interests because of the “externally penetrated character of US hegemony after 1945 ” (Ikenberry 2001b :206), giving them substantial ownership of these institutional arrangements.

On this reading the ideological and intersubjective consensus on hegemonic arrangements not only permeates the interiors of states but has, effectively, become an essential element of the subjective identity of political elites in associative states (Ikenberry and Kupchan 1990 :283). Indeed, for Ikenberry ( 2001a :198; 2001b ), Europeans after 1945 were more worried about American withdrawal and abandonment than domination, which echoes Gier Lundestad’s ( 1998 ) idea of the postwar transatlantic alliance as an “empire by (European) invitation.”

Ikenberry’s work has provided an interesting and useful entry point for wider debates on globalization and global governance and how such developments have shaped the structures and operations of state/great power. However, it has been subject to a number of criticisms. In the first place there is the problem of the spatial dimensions of hegemonic orders applicable to both the British case and the post- 1945 and post–Cold War American one. This is particularly so with regard to the degree to which the hegemon develops institutions that bind it to other states and which “facilitate consultation and joint-decision-making” (Ikenberry 2001c :20–1). While this may apply to relations within the core, this is not the case with much of the periphery, where consultation has tended to be limited and joint decision-making much less in evidence (Augelli and Murphy 1988 ; Gill 2003 ; Soederberg 2006 ). The reason for this is because of (1) the enduring importance of hierarchy and asymmetric power, which means that the United States can compel some states to do things through a range of sanctions it can deploy; and (2) the fact that the socioeconomic and ideological structures, networks, and connections that exist between the United States and other developed capitalist states do not really exist in US relations with these weaker states in the South (Augelli and Murphy 1988 ). These relationships, critics argue, are better understood as imperial rather than hegemonic (Harvey 2005 ; Soederberg 2006 ).

Regarding Ikenberry ’s claim that the domestic properties of the American state allow numerous and competing points of access, Andrew Hurrell ( 2005 :46–7) suggests this claim may overstate the means available to secondary states, particularly from the global South, to gain access to decision-making centers within the US polity. Further, Hurrell argues that it also tends to exaggerate the degree of pluralism within the US political system and the degree to which external and alternative viewpoints can be accommodated. Thus, within Ikenberry’s argument there seems to be an implicit assumption about agreed viewpoints. However, this overlooks the rather narrowly circumscribed ideas as to what has been acceptable to the ears of US policy makers, notable when states – in some instances mandated through democratic means – have tried to implement forms of political economy at odds with the US vision and which have been on the end of US hostility and coercion, as was the case through much of the Cold War (Saull, 2007 :155–64).

Critical Views

Critical views of hegemony distinguish themselves from the traditional perspectives discussed above through situating and embedding state power and behavior within the socioeconomic structure of capitalism, and, further, focusing on class agency as central to the establishment and evolution of hegemonic orders. To varying degrees these scholars have drawn on the theory of hegemony developed by the Italian Marxist theorist Antonio Gramsci ( 1971 ). Written during the interwar period, Gramsci’s broader political economy within which his theory of hegemony emerged was aimed at addressing what he saw as two important weaknesses in both the theoretical framework and political project of historical materialism: (1) the tendency toward structural or economic determinism in the analysis of capitalist development evident in Marx’s later work and in the orthodox political position of European Social Democracy; and (2) the excessively voluntarist theorization of revolutionary political agency developed by Lenin in response to this economism. Gramsci’s theory, then, was concerned with accounting for the reproduction of capitalist dominance and exploitation within the leading capitalist states of his day. His answer lay in the way in which capitalist social property relations are constructed as a “common sense” through the embedding and reproduction of a cultural, ideational, and normative consensus within wider social layers beyond those that occupy positions of material power. In other words, subordinated and exploited social layers were regarded as – to varying degrees – willing participants in the reproduction of hierarchical arrangements that benefited other social groups.

The focus in this section will be on those scholars who have developed and applied Gramsci’s theory of hegemony to international order (Cox 1983 ; 1987 ; 1994 ; Gill and Law 1989 ; Rupert 1990 ; 1995 ; 2000 ; Gill 1995 ; 2003 ; Cox and Sinclair 1996 ; Robinson 2001 ; 2004 ; Morton 2007 ). However, before turning to this tradition of thinking on hegemony, a few remarks will be made about the other tradition of neo-Marxist thinking on hegemony. This tradition is associated with WST and the work of Immanuel Wallerstein ( 1974 ; 1979 ; 1984 ) and Giovanni Arrighi ( 1994 ; 2008 ) in particular.

As mentioned in the introductory comments, this tradition of thinking on hegemony and hegemonic transition in particular predates HST discussions. Originating in the early 1970s with an analytical and political concern to account for the failure of former colonial states to realize meaningful and autonomous economic development after independence, and drawing on a Marxist-informed framework combined with the analysis of long-cycles of capitalist development associated with the work of the French historian Fernand Braudel ( 1974 ), WST centers on the way in which material structures of production and exchange condition geopolitical arrangements.

WST provides a rich vein of socioeconomic analysis of the historical cycles and fluctuations of growth in the world economy since the fifteenth century , and the place of particular regions and states within it, notably through its tripartite hierarchy of core, semiperiphery, and periphery in the workings of the world economy. Further, WST outlines a novel approach to thinking about hegemony compared with most other theories in that, first, it expands its coverage of historical cases of hegemony beyond that of Britain and the United States to include the Netherlands in the seventeenth century (Arrighi 1994 ). In consequence, it outlines a broad general theory of hegemony centered on the competition of leading economies for access to/control of global economic resources that can accommodate a number of varied historical experiences. Second, it implicitly attacks Eurocentric assumptions in much writing on world history through stressing the exceptional character of European/Western dominance from the seventeenth century in contrast to the prior dominance of Asia (see Frank 1998 ) within the world economy. Third, it takes a relational approach to understanding hierarchy within the world economy through focusing on the distribution of benefits (economic surplus) from the (exploitative) workings of the world economy through core and periphery, or what is more commonly referred to as “North–South,” relations.

While these distinctive qualities of WST suggest a radically different theory of hegemony from traditional views, and HST in particular, the criticisms leveled at WST suggest that its understanding of hegemony has considerable overlap with neorealist variants of HST. First, both traditions focus on states or great powers as repositories of hegemonic power, meaning that the World-Systems approach tends to confine the economic power and structures of a hegemon to a particular territorial orientation. Hegemony, then, is about the material capacities of particular states, and through this material (military and economic) power their dominance and leadership over other states. The problem with this conceptualization of the state is that it tends to collapse state power with the economic capacity and social agency of capital, which is not so territorially confined. For Robinson ( 2004 :130; see Gill 2003 :73–92 also) this ends up reifying state agency rather than situating states in a wider constellation of social agency.

Secondly, what marks out a hegemon is the dominance of a single state based on its asymmetrical material capacities. According to Wallerstein ( 1984 ), hegemony concerns “[t]hat situation in which ongoing rivalry between the so-called ‘great powers’ is so unbalanced that one power is truly primus inter pares ; that is, one power can largely impose its rules and its wishes (at the very least by effective veto power) in the economic, political, military, diplomatic and even cultural arenas.” Thus, there is a tendency to neglect the role of institutions as mediating structures on power imbalances and the ideational, cultural, and intersubjective dimensions of hegemonic order, which may operate autonomously of the rate of decline in the technological and material power of a hegemon. Thus, as Gill ( 2003 :80) notes, even if we accept a material tendency of decline as evidenced in the relative performance of the US economy vis-à-vis the other major advanced capitalist economies since the late 1960s, this does not automatically , or will necessarily, trigger a rupture in the political, ideational, and institutional structures of hegemonic power.

The third area of overlap is that both stress that the histories of hegemonic orders is one of rise and decline. For World-Systems thinkers, the dynamic of decline concerns economic competition whereby contenders catch up, triggering a crisis in the hegemon’s power. Initially this occurs in the productive (manufacturing) sphere of accumulation, before moving on to the commercial and financial spheres. For Arrighi ( 1994 :27–84) the dynamic of rise and decline is more about declines in the productive expansion of hegemons due to the pressure of overcompetition and how this triggers financial innovation and expansion. This is regarded as the final stage of hegemonic power and the moment when hegemonic power declines, giving way to instability and interstate conflict, involving systemic war, before a new hegemon arises. This is broadly how Arrighi ( 2008 :93) sees the current global financial crisis, with the likely outcome of a new hegemon – China – emerging to replace the United States.

For WST critics (Cox 1987 ; Rupert 1995 ; Gill 2003 :73–92; Robinson 2004 :33–84) this reads as a form of structural-economic determinism in a similar fashion to the way in which neorealists’ view the history of the international system as a sequence of cyclical changes in great power dominance. Further, where social or class agency is discussed, it tends to be subordinated to the state and its specific place within the core–periphery hierarchy of the world system, rather than recognizing its more autonomous and dynamic character (Rupert 1995 ; 2000 ; Robinson 2004 :130). Finally, according to Cox ( 1987 ; see also Skocpol 1977 ; Teschke 2003 :137–9) the explanatory power of World-System’s concept of hegemony appears heavily diluted by the breadth of its historical coverage, applied, as it is, to what Arrighi and Wallerstein regard as the “three hegemonies of the capitalist world system” – the Netherlands in the seventeenth century , Britain in the nineteenth century , and the United States after 1945 . Such a wide variety of historical experiences of international order are kept together by their definition of capitalism – hierarchical and exploitative exchange relations – which does not sufficiently recognize the key transformations in the global economy, particularly in the realm of production relations and the associated dynamics of social conflict.

Classes, Historical Blocs and World Order

The theorization of hegemony from a Gramscian perspective emerged in the early 1980s, in part as a response to what its leading proponent – Robert Cox – saw as the structuralism and economism of existing Marxist-informed treatments represented by WST, and assisted by Cox’s unique intellectual viewpoint on the apparatus and workings of international organizations and global governance through his work in the International Labour Organization. In his seminal article ( 1983 ), Cox sought to apply Gramsci’s thinking on hegemony as outlined in the Prison Notebooks ( 1971 ) to the international sphere. What followed was the development of this theoretical framework in a more historically focused assessment of British and American experiences of hegemony (Cox 1987 ), through to discussions of American decline and globalization (Gill and Law 1989 ; Gill 1995 ; 2003 ; Cox 1994 ; Robinson 2001 ; 2004 ), paralleling the accounts offered by traditional approaches to hegemony, and historical accounts of the construction of world hegemonic order (Rupert 1990 ; 1995 ).

This reading of hegemony is distinct from the other approaches discussed, in a number of ways. First, in contrast to the other approaches that tend to focus on the state – be it its material dimension or its subjective identity – Gramscian approaches prioritize an analysis on, and aim to locate hegemony within, historically evolving social structures associated with forms of socioeconomic production (Cox 1987 ; Gill 1993a ). Further, hegemony resides not just in state power and legitimacy, but also within wider civil society (not just the economy) through the reproduction in the daily lives of people and groups of a cultural and ideational disposition toward particular social, economic, and political arrangements. Consequently, historical structures are “partly constituted by consciousness and action of individuals and groups” (Gill 1993b :22). This permits the exercise of hegemony through noncoercive and consensual practices (Cox 1983 ) and highlights the role of so-called “organic intellectuals” (Morton 2007 :92) and, more broadly, communicative and ideational factors in the reproduction of hierarchical power relations as a “common sense” (Rupert 2000 ). As Cox comments, “hegemony is a form in which dominance is obscured by achieving an appearance of acquiescence […] As if it were the natural order of things [it] is an internalised coherence which has most probably arisen from externally imposed rules but has been transformed into an intersubjectively constituted reality” ( 1994 :366). It is not the case, then, that the material and coercive power of the state/hegemon is insignificant, but, rather, that it is latent and only visible in moments of crisis. Because hegemonic order is diffused in a decentralized and “nonpolitical” fashion through civil society, it is not required as a systemic element of hegemonic order (Cox 1983 :164).

Secondly, the neo-Gramscian focus on social structures, and capitalism in particular, stresses the importance of social forces or classes as the agents or bearers of hegemony. Hegemony, then, is, in the first instance, a form of class rule, not a geopolitical hierarchy of states (Morton 2007 :117) or an interelite consensus based on shared social purposes. These social forces are understood as combinations of ideas, institutions, and material capabilities that Gramsci calls a “historical bloc.” This refers to the social, economic, and political connections between the administrative and coercive machinery of the state and social groupings within civil society whereby leading qua capitalist social forces establish ascendancy over other social groupings but do so through incorporating them into the structures of state and governance as subaltern partners. Thus the historical bloc is more than just a political alliance, but rather the integration of a variety of class interests which are propagated throughout society in a way that promotes not just a harmony of political and economic aims, but also a wider cultural and moral unity (Morton 2007 :118). Such arrangements can be identified, empirically, at the level of production relations (i.e., the relationship to ownership and/or control of the means of production), state–society relations (political parties, civil society organizations, and ideological currents), and internationally in terms of the organization of world order and the international institutions that uphold particular socioeconomic and political arrangements. Consequently, through linking the organization of production relations with the “superstructure” of civil and political society, neo-Gramscians aim to overcome what they regard as the economism of the World-Systems approach.

Through this focus on social forces, neo-Gramscian approaches seek to (1) avoid static or deterministic accounts of hegemonic order through focusing on how such orders are reproduced through concrete agency and the construction of particular institutional arrangements at the state and international levels; and (2) incorporate a theorization of resistance to hegemonic orders and the possibilities for the emergence of counterhegemonies, as well as the prolongation of hegemonic arrangements through the emergence of new historical blocs (see Morton 2007 ; Rupert 2000 ). This results in a much more open-ended and fluid conception of hegemony in that it highlights the dynamic relationship between the state and civil society, as well as offering a different spatial understanding of hegemony (see Agnew 2005 ) through mapping out the ways in which hegemony operates internationally through multiple channels and connections involving states, international institutions (the Bretton Woods institutions, the WTO, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) and wider civil society forces organized at the domestic and international levels. This is something that I will come back to in a moment when I discuss neo-Gramscian discussions of globalization.

In attempting to correct what they regard as more economistic and deterministic readings of Marxism through emphasizing the subjective and ideationally constructed reproduction of material relations involving conscious human agency, neo-Gramscians have been accused of paying insufficient attention to the role of socioeconomic structures in the constitution of hegemony (Joseph 2002 ; 2008 ). Simply put, for a social group to be hegemonic within a social order it must be structurally located within the economy to ensure its wider social leadership and, as such, any reference to intersubjectivity “is grounded in real material structures” (Joseph 2008 :114). By putting so much stress on the intersubjective – hegemony is “inscribed in the mind” (Cox and Sinclair 1996 :245) – and ideational reproduction of hierarchical class relationships, the neo-Gramscian theory of hegemony fails to recognise the objectivity of the material structure of capitalism. The consequence of this is a tendency to regard (material) structures and subjective agency as mutually constitutive (Joseph 2008 :118–19) and, consequently, a failure to recognize the constraining and directing dimensions of historical structures.

What is central to the Gramscian theoretical framework just outlined is the requirement of historical and empirical investigation to determine the specificities of a particular hegemonic order and the distinct social and political interests represented within it (Cox 1983 :162; Gill 2003 :30–5). Thus Cox ( 1987 ) has outlined accounts of the particularities of British and American hegemony, and Mark Rupert ( 1990 ; 1995 ) has provided a historical analysis of the emergence of a historical bloc associated with the American-led postwar international economy, as well as more recent developments related to neoliberal globalization (Rupert 2000 ). In his account, the domestic sociopolitical arrangements within the United States during the 1930s – which saw organized labor incorporated into a new social and political consensus (the New Deal social contract between capital and labor) – was internationalized after World War II. This rested on a new mode of capital accumulation – Fordism – which itself was associated with a new set of social, cultural, and ideological norms, and configured, politically, through institution building that incorporated a range of social interests under the hierarchical leadership of a transnational liberal capitalist class. Through a combination of American state and civil society efforts, and assisted by the deus ex machina of the Cold War, such arrangements were emulated in other leading capitalist states, thus resulting in the establishment of an international historical bloc through the extension of US methods of production, exchange, and consumption.

While articulating a historically grounded account of hegemony formation and development, these historical accounts of hegemony have also exposed frailties in the broader theory of hegemony, suggesting that, like its HST counterpart, neo-Gramscian hegemony may have a more limited theoretical range than its proponents recognize. This is particularly so with regard to the identification of British nineteenth-century international leadership as hegemonic in a sense comparable to that of the Pax Americana. Thus, as Hannes Lacher ( 2006 :122) has remarked, while HST amounts to a cyclical theory of the rise and fall of great powers, so the Gramscian theory of hegemony amounts to a recurring cycle of the rise and fall of historical blocs. However, contra neo-Gramscian historicism, and this account of hegemony, viz. consensual relations of domination, such structures and relations have only been present within the postwar experience of American leadership. The historical bloc of so-called Pax Britannica was a much more limited construct than that of the postwar case. Thus the civil society elements of British hegemony were simply not evident within the polities of other leading capitalist states, in part because the socioeconomic changes taking place within these states were in significant measure in response to British geopolitical and geo-economic pressure. Further, rather than supporting liberal, laissez-faire elements involved in domestic political struggles within many of these states, British policy tended to be committed to upholding the rule of the ancien régime (Lacher 2006 :123). Put another way, there was no historical bloc in the British case, at least not in the developed and institutionalized sense of the post- 1945 international economic order. Consequently, the theoretical purchase of neo-Gramscian hegemony is weakened in the face of historical specificity.

As with the other approaches to hegemony previously discussed, neo-Gramscians have also sought to outline an explanation of developments in world politics since the 1970s associated with American decline, and globalization. The work of Bill Robinson ( 2001 ; 2004 ) and John Agnew ( 2005 ) in particular stand out in developing a Gramscian-informed reading of developments since the 1970s. These accounts have sought to identify a transnational form of hegemony that is, increasingly, separate from any single territorial concentration of political and economic power. Thus Robinson ( 2004 :21) states that the postwar historical bloc has been transformed through the combined processes of American decline and globalization, with the dominance of transnational capital over other – locally and regionally oriented – capitals becoming the hegemonic fraction of capital. This development has been accompanied by the establishment of what amounts to a transnational state apparatus organized within global governance institutions (IMF, WTO, European Union, North American Free Trade Agreement) that have emerged out of the 1970s Trilateral Commission and involving international bureaucrats, heads of state and the chief executives of transnational capital. This is evidenced in the increasing use of global governance mechanisms such as the WTO, IMF and World Bank to deal with economic crises and to guarantee private property rights, while the United Nations and the North Atlantic Treaty Organization have been involved in providing security and policing roles (Robinson 2004 :75–6, 113–20). While these developments are not yet able to provide a singular regime of regulation for the global reproduction of capital, what we are witnessing, and what they demonstrate, according to Robinson, is the decline in US power/hegemony and the emergence of a new decentered, transnational hegemonic order. (Robinson 2004 :101).

John Agnew’s ( 2005 ) work has outlined a similar argument through the globalization of what he calls “market-place society.” Although the socioeconomic arrangements of “marketplace society” first emerged in the United States in the nineteenth century and have been spread beyond it through the actions of the US state, their globalization and absorption and adoption by other societies have been much more a product of the multiple and uncoordinated activities of American society (Agnew 2005 :3, 20). The consequence of these decentered and disjointed patterns of relations means that hegemony cannot – at least in this particular historical moment – be understood as a territorializing and homogenizing form of power, but rather a networked and fragmented one which has radical and uneven consequences for the organization of political space (Agnew 2005 :8). Although Agnew is a little more circumspect about the degree to which such developments are associated with the emergence of transnational state-like institutions, he shares Robinson’s understanding of globalization as a new mode of capital accumulation, what he calls the “market-access system” (Agnew 2005 :145), which has undermined American economic power and has put increasing pressure on the domestic social and political coalition that has supported such developments since the 1970s.

To varying degrees, then, neo-Gramscian analyses converge with the other approaches to hegemony (although the routes they have taken to get to this analytical destination and the conceptual vehicles employed to get there have been different) in speaking of a moment of crisis and transformation in the organizing principles of hegemony that have prevailed since the 1970s. While HST and World-Systems theory remain within state-centric ontologies looking for a new territorialized hegemony to succeed that of the Pax Americana, thus ending the period of instability, for neo-Gramscians, and Robinson and Agnew in particular, the historical momentum seems to be moving toward something that supersedes state territoriality with the establishment of a transnational historical bloc. This would involve the coordination of local, national, and regional political and economic developments through a more coordinated set of transnational arrangements so as to better facilitate global patterns of accumulation and resting less on the declining significance of territoriality but, rather, the determining significance of state borders.

Whether or not this comes to pass, the account of political and economic developments since the 1970s – the era of globalization – is open to contestation. Thus, while the Bush doctrine and its attendant difficulties in the Middle East and central Asia may be regarded as evidence of American decline (Robinson 2004 ; Agnew 2005 :3), the United States continues – and is likely to do so for the near future – to have a unique place in the current world order with regard to its indispensability in the use of armed force and in its involvement in, if not resolution of, regional conflicts (Brooks 2008 ). This, itself, should give some pause for thought about talk of a transnational state when the coercive capabilities of order are so concentrated within a single state and when the deployment of that force may have wider and beneficial consequences for other states but continues to be particularly concerned with US national security considerations.

While military power continues to resemble a more realist depiction of world politics, economic relations and patterns of economic development, though more varied, do not reflect a globalized structure but rather a much more uneven and regionally concentrated set of developments (Hirst et al. 2009 ). This relates to the broader neo-Gramscian conceptualization of class agency – both ruling and subaltern. With regard to the former there is a tendency to treat the so-called transnational ruling class or historical bloc as a virtually autonomous entity. This tendency to exaggerate the “institutional and ideological self-representation” (Colás 2002 :200–1) of this social grouping not only overlooks the continuing way in which such “transnational” entities are constituted by national and local political and economic dynamics (i.e., the geography of borders still matters), but also the way that the agency of dominant classes is constituted through the exploitation of subordinate classes (Colas 2002 :200). This last point also relates to the question of resistance and contestation – cited as a constitutive dimension of hegemony – but largely absent (an important exception being Morton 2002 ) in the theoretical and historical/empirical accounts provided by neo-Gramscians (Colás 2002 ; Hobson 2007 ).

As this essay has demonstrated, there is a rich and varied literature on the theory and history of hegemony within IPE. As has been indicated throughout, much of this discussion has been fueled by ongoing developments in the world economy. Consequently, the economic rise of China and the political and geopolitical possibilities that flow from this add a new layer of empirical complexity and theoretical challenge to existing positions that are likely to dominate future debates about hegemony in IPE.

  • Agnew, John (2005) Hegemony: The New Shape of Global Power . Philadelphia: Temple University Press.
  • Arrighi, Giovanni (1994) The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power and the Origins of Our Times . London: Verso.
  • Arrighi, Giovanni (2008) Adam Smith in Beijing: Lineages of the Twenty-First Century . London: Verso.
  • Augelli, Enrico , and Murphy, Craig (1988) America’s Quest for Supremacy and the Third World . London: Pinter.
  • Braudel, Fernand (1974) Capitalism and Material Life 1400–1800 . London: Fontana/Collins.
  • Brooks, Stephen , and Wohlforth, William (2008) World Out of Balance . Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Calleo, David (1987) Beyond American Hegemony . New York: Basic Books.
  • Colás, Alejandro (2002) The Class Politics of Globalisation. In M. Rupert and H. Smith (eds.) Historical Materialism and Globalization . London: Routledge, pp. 191–209.
  • Cox, Robert (1983) Gramsci, Hegemony and International Relations: An Essay in Method. Millennium: Journal of International Studies 12 (2), 62–75.
  • Cox, Robert (1987) Production, Power, and World Order: Social Forces in the Making of History . New York: Columbia University Press.
  • Cox, Robert (1994) The Forum: Hegemony and Social Change. Mershon International Studies Review 38 (2), 366–7.
  • Cox, Robert , and Sinclair, Timothy (eds.) (1996) Approaches to World Order . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Frank, Andre-Gunder (1998) Re-Orient . Berkeley: University of California Press.
  • Gill, Stephen (1993a) Gramsci and Global Politics: Toward a Post-hegemonic Research Agenda. In S. Gill (ed.) Gramsci, Historical Materialism and International Relations . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1–18.
  • Gill, Stephen (1993b) Epistemology, Ontolgy and the “Italian School.” In S. Gill (ed.) Gramsci, Historical Materialism and International Relations . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 21–48.
  • Gill, Stephen (1995) Globalisation, Market Civilization and Disciplinary Neoliberalism. Millennium: Journal of International Studies 24 (3), 399–423.
  • Gill, Stephen (2003) Power and Resistance in the New World Order . Basingstoke: Palgrave.
  • Gill, Stephen , and Law, David (1989) Global Hegemony and the Structural Power of Capital. International Studies Quarterly 33 (4), 475–99.
  • Gilpin, Robert (1972) The Politics of Transnational Economic Relations. In R.O. Keohane and J.S. Nye (eds.) Transnational Relations and World Politics . Cambridge: Harvard University Press, pp. 48–69.
  • Gilpin, Robert (1981) War and Change in World Politics . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Gilpin, Robert (1987) The Political Economy of International Relations . Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Gowa, Joanne (1989) Rational Hegemons, Excludable Goods, and Small Groups: An Epitaph for Hegemonic Stability Theory? World Politics 41, 307–24.
  • Gramsci, Antonio (1971) Selections from the Prison Notebooks of Antonio Gramsci , trans. Q. Hoare and G. Nowell-Smith . New York: International.
  • Grunberg, Isabelle (1990) Exploring the “Myth” of Hegemonic Stability. International Organization 44 (3), 431–77.
  • Guzzini, Stefano (1998) Realism in International Relations and International Political Economy . London: Routledge.
  • Harvey, David (2005) The New Imperialism . Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Hirst, Paul , Thompson, Grahame , and Bromley, Simon (2009) Globalization in Question . Cambridge: Polity.
  • Hobson, John M. (2007) Is Critical Theory Always for the White West and for Western Imperialism? Beyond Westphalian towards a post-Racist IR. Review of International Studies 33, 91–116.
  • Hurrell, Andrew (2005) Power, Institutions and the Production of Inequality. In M. Barnett and R. Duvall (eds.) Power in Global Governance . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 33–58.
  • Ikenberry, G. John (1998) Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Persistence of American Postwar Order. International Security 23 (3), 43–78.
  • Ikenberry, G. John (2001a) After Victory . Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Ikenberry, G. John (2001b) American Power and the Empire of Capitalist Democracy. Review of International Studies 27, 191–212.
  • Ikenberry, G. John (2001c) American Grand Strategy in the Age of Terror. Survival 43 (4), 19–34.
  • Ikenberry, G. John (2004) Illusions of Empire: Defining the New American Order. Foreign Affairs 83 (2), 144–54.
  • Ikenberry, G. John , and Kupchan, Charles (1990) Socialization and Hegemonic Power. International Organization 44 (3), 283–315.
  • Joseph, Jonathan (2002) Hegemony: A Realist Analysis . London: Routledge.
  • Joseph, Jonathan (2008) Hegemony and the Structure–Agency Problem in International Relations: A Scientific Realist Contribution. Review of International Studies 34 (1), 109–28.
  • Kennedy, Paul (1987) The Rise and Fall of Great Powers: Economic Change and Military Conflict 1500 to 2000 . London: Fontana Press.
  • Keohane, Robert O. (1980) The Theory of Hegemonic Stability Theory and Changes in International Economic Regimes, 1967–1977. In O.R. Holsti , R.M. Siverson and A.L. George (eds.) Change in the International System . Boulder: Westview, pp. 131–62.
  • Keohane, Robert O. (1984) After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy . Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Keohane, Robert O. (1989) International Institutions and State Power: Essays in International Relations Theory . Boulder: Westview.
  • Keohane, Robert O. , and Joseph S. Nye (eds.) (1972) Transnational Relations and World Politics . Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
  • Keohane, Robert O. , and Joseph S. Nye (1977) Power and Interdependence . Boston: Little Brown.
  • Kindleberger, Charles (1973) The World in Depression 1929–39 . Berkeley: University of California Press.
  • Kindleberger, Charles (1981) Dominance and Leadership in the International Economy: Exploitation, Public Goods and Free Riders. International Studies Quarterly 25 (2), 242–54.
  • Kindleberger, Charles (1986) International Public Goods without International Government. American Economic Review 76 (1), 1–12.
  • Krasner, Stephen D. (1976) State Power and the Structure of International Trade. World Politics 28 (3), 317–43.
  • Krasner, Stephen D. (1982) American Policy and Global Economic Instability. In W.P. Avery and D.P. Rankin (eds.) America in a Changing World Political Economy . New York: Longman, pp. 29–48.
  • Lacher, Hannes (2006) Beyond Globalization: Capitalism, Territoriality and the International Relations of Modernity . London: Routledge.
  • Lake, David A. (1993) Leadership, Hegemony, and International Political Economy: Naked Emperor or Tattered Monarch with Potential? International Studies Quarterly 37 (4), 459–89.
  • Latham, Robert (1997) The Liberal Moment: Modernity, Security and the Making of the Postwar International Order . New York: Columbia University Press.
  • Lundestad, Gier (1998) “Empire” by Invitation: The United States and European Integration, 1945–1997 . Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Machiavelli, Niccolò (1977) The Prince . New York: W.W. Norton.
  • McKeown, Timothy J. (1983) Hegemonic Stability Theory and Nineteenth Century Tariff Levels in Europe. International Organization 37, 73–91.
  • Mjøset, Lars (1990) The Turn of Two Centuries: A Comparison of British and US Hegemonies. In D. Rankin (ed.) World Leadership and Hegemony . Boulder: Lynne Rienner, pp. 21–47.
  • Morton, Adam (2002) La Resurrección del Maíz: Globalisation, Resistance and the Zapatistas. Millennium: Journal of International Studies 31 (1), 27–54.
  • Morton, Adam (2007) Unravelling Gramsci: Hegemony and Passive Revolution in the Global Economy . London: Pluto Press.
  • Nye, Joseph S. (1990) Bound to Lead: The Changing Nature of American Power . New York: Basic Books.
  • O’Brien, Patrick (2003) Myths of Hegemony. New Left Review 24, 113–34.
  • Panitch, Leo , and Gindin, Sam (2003) Global Capitalism and American Empire. In L. Panitch and C. Leys (eds.) Socialist Register 2004 . London: Merlin Press.
  • Pollard, Robert (1985) Economic Security and the Origins of the Cold War . New York: Columbia University Press.
  • Robinson, William I. (2001) Social Theory and Globalization: The Rise of the Transnational State. Theory and Society 30 (2), 157–200.
  • Robinson, William. I. (2004) A Theory of Global Capitalism: Production, Class, and State in the Transnational World . Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
  • Ruggie, John (1998) Constructing World Polity: Essays on International Organization . London: Routledge.
  • Rupert, Mark (1990) Producing Hegemony: State/Society Relations and the Politics of Productivity in the United States. International Studies Quarterly 34 (4), 427–56.
  • Rupert, Mark (1995) Producing Hegemony: The Politics of Mass Production and American Global Power . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Rupert, Mark (2000) Ideologies of Globalization: Contending Visions of a New World Order . London: Routledge.
  • Saull, Richard (2007) The Cold War and After . London: Pluto Press.
  • Skocpol, Theda (1977) Wallerstein’s World Capitalist System: A Theoretical and Historical Critique. American Journal of Sociology 82 (5), 1075–90.
  • Snidal, D. (1985) The Limits of Hegemonic Stability Theory. International Organization 39 (4), 579–614.
  • Soederberg, Susanne (2006) Global Governance in Question . London: Pluto Press.
  • Stein, A.A. (1984) The Hegemon’s Dilemma: Great Britain, the United States and the International Economic Order. International Organization 38 (2), 355–86.
  • Strange, Susan (1987) The Persistent Myth of Lost Hegemony. International Organization 41 (4), 551–74.
  • Strange, Susan (1988) States and Markets . London: Pinter.
  • Strange, Susan (1996) Retreat of the State . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Teschke, Benno (2003) The Myth of 1648 . London: Verso.
  • Wallerstein, Immanuel (1974) The Modern World-System . New York: Academic Press.
  • Wallerstein, Immanuel (1979) The Capitalist World-Economy . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Wallerstein, Immanuel (1984) The Politics of the World-Economy: The States, the Movements and the Civilizations . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Wyatt-Walter, Andrew (1996) The United States and Western Europe: The Theory of Hegemonic Stability. In N. Woods (ed.) Explaining International Relations since 1945 . Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 126–154.

Links to Digital Materials

Web-based resources are surprisingly thin, particularly with regard to HST. Most sources refer to individual book or journal publications. The coverage of critical, neo-Marxist approaches is more developed.

International Gramsci Society. At www.internationalgramscisociety.org , accessed June 22, 2009. Though dedicated to Gramsci’s thought in general, there are numerous contributions addressing the question of hegemony in International Political Economy.

Institute for Research on World-Systems. At www.irows.ucr.edu/ , accessed June 22, 2009. Online home of World-Systems Theory, containing articles addressing WST approaches to hegemony.

Hegemonic Stability Theory. At www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/intrel/hegstab.htm , accessed June 22, 2009. Contains a number of articles relating to HST.

Centre for Research on Globalization. At www.globalresearch.ca , accessed June 22, 2009. Website offering critical commentary on world affairs, with a number of articles on contemporary US hegemony.

US-China Economic and Security Review Commission. At www.uscc.gov/index.php , accessed Aug. 2009. Analysis and reports on US–Sino relations from an official US government body.

Related Articles

  • Historical Sociology and International Relations: Interdisciplinary Approaches to Large-Scale Historical Change and Global Order
  • International Hierarchy
  • Postcolonialism in International Relations
  • Critical Theory: IR's Engagement with the Frankfurt School and Marxism

Printed from Oxford Research Encyclopedias, International Studies. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a single article for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).

date: 27 June 2024

  • Cookie Policy
  • Privacy Policy
  • Legal Notice
  • Accessibility
  • [109.248.223.228]
  • 109.248.223.228

Character limit 500 /500

image of Donald Trump with text "Project 2025"

Inside Project 2025's attack on reproductive rights

Organizations looking to staff and provide policy for a second Trump administration want severe roll-backs on access to surrogacy, IVF, mifepristone, and contraception

Special Programs Abortion Rights & Reproductive Health

Written by Media Matters Staff

Research contributions from Sophie Lawton , Jacina Hollins-Borges , Jack Wheatley , John Knefel , Charis Hoard , Jasmine Geonzon & Audrey McCabe

Published 06/24/24 1:30 PM EDT

Organizations involved in Project 2025 — a broad effort from more than 100 groups within the conservative movement to provide staffing and policy positions to a second Donald Trump administration — have advocated for extreme rollbacks to reproductive rights and access to healthcare.

Inside Project 2025's Attack on Reproductive Rights by Media Matters for America on Scribd

New Media Matters research on Project 2025 partners’ draconian position on reproductive rights

Specifically, Project 2025 partner groups have:

Spread misinformation about contraceptive methods or championed limiting access to contraception, largely on religious grounds.

Published written content, supported legal efforts, or had organizational leadership make comments against the use of safe and effective abortion pills, specifically mifepristone.

Additionally, The Heritage Foundation, America First Legal, and the Center for Renewing America have endorsed reviving the Comstock Act to restrict access to abortion by potentially banning the mailing of all materials that could be used for the procedure

Publicly criticized in vitro fertilization.

Published and presented anti-surrogacy arguments.

Background on Project 2025 and reproductive rights

Project 2025 is a radical right-wing transition plan organized by conservative think tank The Heritage Foundation. The initiative’s nearly 900-page policy book, titled Mandate for Leadership: The Conservative Promise , describes — among many other issues — Project 2025’s plan to attack reproductive rights from several angles. The proposals put forward include removing the term “abortion” from all federal laws and regulations, reversing approval of abortion medications, punishing providers by withdrawing federal health funding, and restricting clinics that provide contraception and STD testing. A chapter in Mandate for Leadership also calls for the next Republican administration to use the Comstock Act , “an 1873 anti-vice law banning the mailing of obscene matter and articles used to produce abortion,” to effectively end “mail-order abortions.”

During a June 22 appearance on MSNBC's  The Weekend , Heritage Foundation President Kevin Roberts underlined Project 2025’s broad ambitions, saying its framework is “going to transcend the next 4 years, the next 10 years.”

The Heritage Foundation has been publishing Mandate for Leadership policy books coinciding with presidential elections since 1980, but this is the first year Heritage has included more than 100 right-wing partner organizations, making it a conservative coalition effort. Beyond what’s in the official policy book, many of the Project 2025 partner organizations — including those with strong ties to Christian nationalism — have also leveled other attacks on reproductive rights. These groups have collectively called for massive restrictions on access to contraception, in vitro fertilization, surrogacy, and abortion drugs such as mifepristone — which are now used in 63% of abortions in the United States.

Key Media Matters research on Project 2025

Media Matters has also recently published thorough research on Project 2025 and the MAGA media universe, including:

  • A resource guide that outlines the specific policy and personnel priorities of Project 2025;
  • A guide to the MAGA media universe;
  • Deep-dive research on what leading MAGA figures expect from a second Trump term;

And a full list of Media Matters content on Project 2025 can be found here .

Numbers, Facts and Trends Shaping Your World

Read our research on:

Full Topic List

Regions & Countries

  • Publications
  • Our Methods
  • Short Reads
  • Tools & Resources

Read Our Research On:

  • Americans’ Views of Government’s Role: Persistent Divisions and Areas of Agreement

3. Americans’ trust in federal government and attitudes toward it

Table of contents.

  • Views on the efficiency of government
  • Views on the government’s regulation of business
  • Confidence in the nation’s ability to solve problems
  • Views on the effect of government aid to the poor
  • Views on government’s role in health care
  • Views on the future of Social Security
  • Trust in government
  • Feelings toward the federal government
  • Acknowledgments
  • The American Trends Panel survey methodology

Americans’ trust in the federal government, which has hovered at or near record lows for nearly 20 years, has modestly increased over the last year. Still, only about two-in-ten Americans say they trust the government in Washington to do what is right.

Frustration also remains the dominant feeling among the public, as it has for two decades – with a 60% majority now saying this. Far smaller shares say the federal government makes them feel either content or angry.

Chart shows Trust in the federal government: 1958-2024

Roughly two-in-ten Americans (22%) say they trust the government in Washington to do what is right just about always or most of the time.

A majority of Americans say they trust the federal government “only some of the time” (59%), while 17% say they never trust it.

Trust in the federal government is up from a year ago, when 16% said they trusted the government at least most of the time.

Trust in the federal government has been consistently low for the last several decades, and today’s level is comparable to levels of trust in 2022 and 2021.

For more on trust in the federal government over the last 70 years, please visit our trust interactive .

Partisan and demographic differences in trust in government

Americans tend to trust the federal government more when the party they associate with holds the White House. Today, 35% of Democrats and Democratic-leaning independents say they trust the government almost always or most of the time, a somewhat larger share than in recent years. As has been the case since the beginning of Joe Biden’s administration, only about one-in-ten Republicans and Republican leaners say they trust the government to do what is right.

Chart shows Trust in the federal government has increased among Democrats

  • Throughout Biden’s presidency, Democrats have been more likely than Republicans to trust the federal government.
  • During Donald Trump’s administration, Republicans expressed higher levels of trust than Democrats did.
  • 7% of conservative Republicans trust the government all or most of the time, compared with 17% of moderate and liberal Republicans.
  • There are no substantial ideological differences among Democrats on this question.

Chart shows Trust in the federal government by race, ethnicity, age, education and political partisanship

Asian (36%), Hispanic (30%) and Black (27%) adults are more likely than White adults (19%) to say they trust the government all or most of the time.

Age and educational differences in trust in government are relatively modest.

Adults under age 50 express somewhat less trust in the federal government than those who are older (20% always/most of the time vs. 25%).

Americans without a college degree (21%) are somewhat less likely than those with a college degree (26%) to say they trust the federal government all or most of the time.

A majority of Americans say they feel frustrated – rather than angry or content – with the federal government. This has been the dominant emotion for much of the last several decades – with the sole exception being the period shortly after Sept. 11, 2001.

Chart shows Most Americans remain frustrated with the federal government; fewer are content or angry

Today, six-in-ten Americans say they feel frustration toward the federal government, while 21% say they feel anger and 18% say they feel basically content.

The balance of Americans’ feelings toward the federal government have been largely unchanged in the last few years.

Partisans’ feelings toward the federal government shift with the occupants of the White House

Chart shows Democrats are more likely to be content with federal government, Republicans are more likely to be angry

Frustration toward the federal government is the dominant emotion for both Republicans and Democrats, regardless of which party is in control of the White House. But partisans’ anger with government is higher when administrations from the other party are in power. Contentment is higher among people who favor the party of the president.

Today, 28% of Democrats and Democratic-leaning independents say they are content. Just 8% of Republicans and Republican leaners say this.

Conversely, 34% of Republicans currently say they feel anger toward the government in Washington. Only one-in-ten Democrats say they are angry.

Sign up for our weekly newsletter

Fresh data delivery Saturday mornings

Sign up for The Briefing

Weekly updates on the world of news & information

  • Election 2024
  • Federal Government
  • Government Spending & the Deficit
  • Health Care
  • Partisanship & Issues
  • Social Security & Medicare
  • Trust in Government

6 facts about presidential and vice presidential debates

Biden, trump are least-liked pair of major party presidential candidates in at least 3 decades, cultural issues and the 2024 election, more than half of americans are following election news closely, and many are already worn out, americans have mixed views about how the news media cover biden’s, trump’s ages, most popular, report materials.

1615 L St. NW, Suite 800 Washington, DC 20036 USA (+1) 202-419-4300 | Main (+1) 202-857-8562 | Fax (+1) 202-419-4372 |  Media Inquiries

Research Topics

  • Email Newsletters

ABOUT PEW RESEARCH CENTER  Pew Research Center is a nonpartisan fact tank that informs the public about the issues, attitudes and trends shaping the world. It conducts public opinion polling, demographic research, media content analysis and other empirical social science research. Pew Research Center does not take policy positions. It is a subsidiary of  The Pew Charitable Trusts .

© 2024 Pew Research Center

ACM Digital Library home

  • Advanced Search

Application of Intelligent Image Recognition and Digital Media Art in the Inheritance of Black Pottery Intangible Cultural Heritage

New citation alert added.

This alert has been successfully added and will be sent to:

You will be notified whenever a record that you have chosen has been cited.

To manage your alert preferences, click on the button below.

New Citation Alert!

Please log in to your account

Information & Contributors

Bibliometrics & citations, index terms.

Information systems

Information systems applications

Multimedia information systems

Multimedia content creation

Recommendations

Constructing a semantic wiki for living cultural heritage: case study of korean tea culture.

In recent years, the amount of digital content related to cultural heritage resources has been growing to such a degree that it can now be easily published and distributed. However, such digital content is limited to material manifestations, such as ...

Cataloging intangible cultural heritage on the web

The E.CH.I. project involves the definition, implementation, population and search of a Register of the intangible cultural legacy of trans-border Italo-Suisse heritage, aiming to design such a register in line with the new heritage paradigm proposed by ...

Dimensions of indigenous heritage discourse and the use of technologies of display in an ethnographic exhibition: a case study of the "Song for the Horse Nation" exhibition (National Museum of the American Indian, New York)

This poster reports on a study of an ethnographic exhibition put together by three indigenous curators and hosted by the National Museum of the American Indian in New York ("A Song for the Horse Nation"). Its aim is to contribute to the scarce Library ...

Information

Published in.

cover image ACM Transactions on Asian and Low-Resource Language Information Processing

Google, USA

Association for Computing Machinery

New York, NY, United States

Publication History

Check for updates, author tags.

  • Cultural heritage
  • intangible cultural heritage: digital media art
  • image recognition technology
  • convolutional neural network
  • cultural heritage
  • Research-article

Funding Sources

  • Shandong Longshan Black pottery cultural heritage protection, inheritance and development research

Contributors

Other metrics, bibliometrics, article metrics.

  • 0 Total Citations
  • 209 Total Downloads
  • Downloads (Last 12 months) 200
  • Downloads (Last 6 weeks) 11

View Options

Login options.

Check if you have access through your login credentials or your institution to get full access on this article.

Full Access

View options.

View or Download as a PDF file.

View online with eReader .

View this article in Full Text.

Share this Publication link

Copying failed.

Share on social media

Affiliations, export citations.

  • Please download or close your previous search result export first before starting a new bulk export. Preview is not available. By clicking download, a status dialog will open to start the export process. The process may take a few minutes but once it finishes a file will be downloadable from your browser. You may continue to browse the DL while the export process is in progress. Download
  • Download citation
  • Copy citation

We are preparing your search results for download ...

We will inform you here when the file is ready.

Your file of search results citations is now ready.

Your search export query has expired. Please try again.

IMAGES

  1. (PDF) Media Hegemony

    research on media hegemony

  2. (PDF) Globalization, Media Hegemony, and Social Class

    research on media hegemony

  3. Hegemony and Media Framing by on Prezi

    research on media hegemony

  4. Hegemony, counter hegemony, and media alternative challenges

    research on media hegemony

  5. (PDF) Consumer Hegemony on Social Media in the Digital Disruption Era

    research on media hegemony

  6. (PDF) Post-Truth: Hegemony on Social Media and Implications for

    research on media hegemony

COMMENTS

  1. (PDF) Media Hegemony

    336. Media Hegemony. Media hegemony occurs when a particular political economic structure of media. institutions and associated production, distribution, and ideological practices are. dominant ...

  2. (PDF) Media Hegemony: A Failure of Perspective

    Specifically, the notion of media. hegemony includes assumptions about (1) the socialization and ideol-. ogy of journalists, (2) the tendency of journalists and their reports to. support and ...

  3. Mass Media and Hegemonic Knowledge : Gramsci and the ...

    The concept of hegemony dominates Gramsci's work (especially Prison Notebooks 1971) and cannot be isolated from other concepts, such as consent, coercion, superstructure and intellectuals, that Gramsci employed in order to explain how the modern state and its institutions work.This research aims to provide a holistic approach to Gramsci's hegemony and its relation to media discourse.

  4. What is hegemony now? Transformations in media, political economy, and

    dominance of corporate media hegemony is simultaneously aided and hampered by the tenuous system of national segmentations, streaming service overlap and often ... the Pew Research Center has tracked the way news consumption has shifted from mainstream print and broadcast outlets to social media, with older demographics ...

  5. PDF Are Social Media Emancipatory or Hegemonic Societal Effects of Mass

    that social media emancipate communication structurally, but impose hegemony on content, we uncover a paradox high-lighting need for further research on societal impacts of mass media digitization. We also note the practical implications of our work for activists, policy makers, and digital media

  6. Media Hegemony: A Failure of Perspective

    for more research on the mass media. A central issue underlying much of this research is control and dominance of the news process. This essay analyzes the logical and empirical adequacy of media hegemony as an explanation of ideological dominance. Analysis of recent research shows that some researchers have uncritically adapted the

  7. Media hegemony

    Media hegemony is a perceived process by which certain values and ways of thought promulgated through the mass media become dominant in society. It is seen in particular as reinforcing the capitalist system. Media hegemony has been presented as influencing the way in which reporters in the media - themselves subject to prevailing values and norms - select news stories and put them across.

  8. Media hegemony

    The theory, derived from Gramscian Marxism, that an elite controls the mass media, and that the media promote the dominant ideology. See also consciousness industry; hegemony; manufacture of consent. The audience is not necessarily compliant (see dominant reading; negotiated reading; oppositional reading).'Corporate media hegemony' refers to the global dominance and influence of powerful ...

  9. Hegemony and the Media

    Abstract. Before it was applied to academic analysis of the media, the term "hegemony" referred more generally to indirect political control, which often replaced the need for constant and direct military or political domination of the kind exercised, for example, by colonial states over rivals or by dominant groups within a nation-state.

  10. PDF Mass Media and Hegemonic Knowledge: GramsciGramsci and the ...

    56 S. Boukala 3.1 A Neo-Gramscian Approach to Media Discourse ˜e concept of hegemony dominates Gramsci's work (especially Prisono Notebooks 1971) and cannot be isolated from other concepts, such as consent, coercion, superstructure and intellectuals, that Gramsci employed in order to explain how the modern state and its institutions work.

  11. PDF Hegemony in Social Media and the effect of recommendations

    distrust in the media, especially social media and algorithmic rec-ommendations, to represent each viewpoint fairly. This lack of trust has dangerous consequences and often accompanies accusations of dishonesty. Here we explore an alternative explanation where this chasm comes from a natural hegemony emerging from root causes

  12. A critical evaluation of debates examining the media hegemony thesis

    More specifically, it defines the concept of hegemony and it explores research supporting and criticizing the media hegemony thesis. The analysis identifies some of the central issues confronting these varied interpretations and concludes by suggesting a number of ways to refine research exploring the news media's production of hegemonic ...

  13. Media Hegemony: A Failure of Perspective

    Abstract. Numerous studies of TV news have been published since Gans's (1972) call for more research on the mass media. A central issue underlying much of this research is control and dominance of the news process. This essay analyzes the logical and empirical adequacy of media hegemony as an explanation of ideological dominance.

  14. Media, Ideology and Hegemony

    Media, Ideology and Hegemony. Media, Ideology and Hegemony contains a range of topics that provide readers with opportunities to think critically about the new digital world. This includes work on old and new media, on the corporate power structure in communication and information technology, and on government use of media to control citizens.

  15. Globalization, Media Hegemony, and Social Class

    This research explores the nature and operation of religious hegemony in gaming journalism through in-depth interviews with gaming journalists (n=17) and a narrative framing textual analysis of ...

  16. (PDF) A Culturalist Approach to the Concept of the Mediatization of

    The fifth argument borrowed from Blumler and Kavanagh (1999) to propose the arrival of the ''fourth age'' of political communication, consisting of the mediatization of politics—the age of media hegemony. Media hegemony does not point to a one-way process or to a deterministic abstraction: It suggests the ways in which the various ...

  17. Hegemony, Ideology, Media in: Media, Ideology and Hegemony

    "Hegemony, Ideology, Media" published on 04 Sep 2018 by Brill. "Hegemony, Ideology, Media" published on 04 Sep 2018 by Brill. Jump to Content. 中文 ... Open Access and Research Funding. Open Access for Librarians. Open Access for Academic Societies. Discover Brill's Open Access Content. About About: Organization: Stay Updated:

  18. PDF Media,Democracy, Hegemony

    This question will lead us to the theory of "cultural hege-mony.". The word hegemony can be briefly defined as "domination.". 1. In this case, it is the domination of a people's culture—ways of thinking, believing, and behaving—by those who own the culture's "idea facto-ries," such as the mass media.

  19. Role of Media in Hegemony and Subcultures

    The book dealt with the invisible force and ROLE OF MEDIA IN HEGEMONY & SUBCULTURES 1 fCaballero, G., Matta, E., Fiedler, M., Vukmirovic, A., 2014 the significant substance behind subcultural groups such as the punks, the rastafarians and the teddy boys (Hebdige, 1979). A subculture is a group that symbolically violates the social order of ...

  20. PDF Global Media Hegemony and The Transformation Bliss in Post ...

    This article presents a conceptual analysis of the relationship between global media hegemony and transformation trajectories within post-colonial African states. It acknowledges that, following the attainment of independence, most African governments adopted the developmental state paradigm to redress erstwhile colonial practices in ...

  21. Fake News as Political Communication: On Fake News, Digital Media and

    Mare Admire. 2020. "Fake News, 2020, Quoted in Moyo, Dumisani, Admire Mare and Hayes Mawindi Mabweazara. "Editorial: Social Media, the Press, and the Crisis of Disinformation in Africa." Communicatio: South African Journal for Communication Theory & Research 46 (4): 1-6.

  22. Revisiting hegemony: A Gramscian analysis for contemporary social work

    Secondly, there is a resurgence of interest in Gramscian analyses for social work in the present era (Carey and Foster, 2011; Garrett, 2008, 2009).Notwithstanding some headway (Garrett, 2008), arguably what remains outstanding is further analyses that offer an accessible introduction to Gramsci for an international readership.Within the present analysis, response to this line of reasoning will ...

  23. Toward equity: Power, cultural hegemony, and organizations

    Power is a product and result of cultural hegemony. Following Williams (1978), cultural hegemony can be understood as the processes and relationships through which dominant groups maintain their positions, and through which subordinated groups either unconsciously acquiesce or mount challenges. Hegemonic processes both draw on and reinforce ...

  24. Hegemony and the Global Political Economy

    Hegemony emerged as an analytical term to conceptualize different historical periods out of the combined post-1945 historical context of two key events: the dissolution of an international political order founded upon European colonial empires, and the establishment and evolution of a postwar liberal international economy under U.S. leadership.

  25. Top newspapers fixate on Biden's age

    Research/Study Study: Top newspapers fixate on Biden's age. Over the past five months, five of the top US newspapers have published nearly 10 times as many articles focused just on Biden's age or ...

  26. Heritage Foundation President Kevin Roberts: Project 2025 framework

    Heritage Foundation President Kevin Roberts: Project 2025 framework will carry on for the next 10 years. Written by Media Matters Staff

  27. Inside Project 2025's attack on reproductive rights

    Project 2025 is a radical right-wing transition plan organized by conservative think tank The Heritage Foundation. The initiative's nearly 900-page policy book, titled Mandate for Leadership ...

  28. Science of social media's effect on mental health isn't as clear cut as

    Future research should focus on following trends over time - tracking the mental health of the same children before and after exposure to social media to see what effects it has - and digging ...

  29. 3. Americans' trust in federal government and attitudes toward it

    ABOUT PEW RESEARCH CENTER Pew Research Center is a nonpartisan fact tank that informs the public about the issues, attitudes and trends shaping the world. It conducts public opinion polling, demographic research, media content analysis and other empirical social science research. Pew Research Center does not take policy positions.

  30. Application of Intelligent Image Recognition and Digital Media Art in

    Research on the application of digital media art in animation control based on Maya MEL language. Acta Techn. CSAV (Ceskoslovensk Akad. Ved.) 62, 1 (2017), 499-507.